Open list explained

Open list describes any variant of party-list proportional representation where voters have at least some influence on the order in which a party's candidates are elected. This is as opposed to closed list, in which party lists are in a predetermined, fixed order by the time of the election and gives the general voter no influence at all on the position of the candidates placed on the party list.

An open list system allows voters to select individuals rather than, or in addition to parties. Different systems give the voter different amounts of influence to change the default ranking. The voter's candidate choices are usually called preference vote; the voters are usually allowed one or more preference votes for the open list candidates.

Open lists differ from mixed-member proportional representation, also known as "personalized proportional representation" in Germany. Some mixed systems, however, may use open lists in their list-PR component.

Variants

Relatively closed

A "relatively closed" open list system is one where a candidate must reach a full electoral quota of votes on their own to be assured of winning a seat. The total number of seats won by the party minus the number of its candidates that achieved this quota gives the number of unfilled seats. These are then successively allocated to the party's not-yet-elected candidates who were ranked highest on the party list.

Examples

Iceland: In both parliamentary and municipal elections, voters may alter the order of the party list or strike candidates from the list completely. How many votes need to be altered in this way to have an effect on the results varies by the number of seats won by the party in the constituency or municipality in question and the candidate's place on the list.[1] In the parliamentary elections of 2007 and 2009, voters altered the party lists enough to change the ranking of candidates within party lists. However, this did not affect which candidates ultimately got elected to parliament.[2]

Norway: In parliamentary elections, 50% of the voters need to vote for a candidate in order to change the order of the party list, meaning that, in practice, it is almost impossible for voters to change the result and it is de facto a closed list system. In county elections there is a threshold of 8%.[3]

More open

In a "more open" list system, the quota for election could be lowered from the above amount. It is then (theoretically) possible that more of a party's candidates achieve this quota than the total seats won by the party. It should therefore be made clear in advance whether list ranking or absolute votes take precedence in that case. The quota for individuals is usually specified either as a percentage of the party list quota, or as a percentage of the total votes received by the party.

Example: The quota is 1000 votes and the open list threshold is specified as 25% of the quota, i.e. 250 votes. Therefore, a party which received 5000 votes wins five seats, which are awarded to its list candidates as follows:

Candidate position
on the list
Preference votes25% of the quotaElected
  1. 1
3500x (first)x
  1. 2
50x
  1. 3
150x
  1. 4
250x (third)x
  1. 5
100
  1. 6
100
  1. 7
450x (second)x
  1. 8
50

\vdots

Candidates #1, #7 and #4 have each achieved 25% of the quota (250 preference votes or more). They get the first three of the five seats the party has won. The other two seats will be taken by #2 and #3, the two highest remaining positions on the party list. This means that #5 is not elected even though being the fifth on the list and having more preference votes than #2.

In practice, with such a strict threshold, only very few candidates succeed to precede on their lists as the required number of votes is huge. Where the threshold is lower (e.g. in Czech parliamentary elections, 5% of the total party vote is the required minimum), results defying the original list order are much more common.

Parties usually allow candidates to ask for preference votes, but without campaigning negatively against other candidates on the list.

Austria

The members of the National Council are elected by open list proportional representation in nine multi-member constituencies based on the states (with varying in size from 7 to 36 seats) and 39 districts. Voters are able to cast a single party vote and one preference votes each on the federal, state and electoral district level for their preferred candidates within that party. The thresholds for a candidate to move up the list are 7% of the candidate's party result on the federal level, 10% on the state level and 14% on the electoral district level.[4] Candidates for the district level are listed on the ballot while voters need to write-in their preferred candidate on state and federal level.

Croatia

In Croatia, the voter can give their vote to a single candidate on the list, but only candidates who have received at least 10% of the party's votes take precedence over the other candidates on the list.[5]

Czech Republic

In Czech parliamentary elections, voters are given 4 preference votes. Only candidates who have received more than 5% of preferential votes at the regional level take precedence over the list.[6] For elections to the European Parliament, the procedure is identical but each voter is only allowed 2 preference votes.

Indonesia

See main article: Elections in Indonesia. In Indonesia, any candidate who has obtained at least 30% of the quota is automatically elected.[7]

Netherlands

In the Netherlands, the voter can give their vote to any candidate in a list (for example, in elections for the House of the Representatives); the vote for this candidate is called a "preference vote" (voorkeurstem in Dutch). Candidate with at least 25% of the quota takes priority over the party's other candidates who stand higher on the party list but received fewer preference votes. Most people vote for the top candidate, to indicate no special preference for any individual candidate, but support for the party in general. Sometimes, however, people want to express their support for a particular person. Many women, for example, vote for the first woman on the list. If a candidate gathers enough preference votes, then they get a seat in parliament, even if their position on the list would leave them without a seat. In the 2003 elections Hilbrand Nawijn, the former minister of migration and integration, was elected into parliament for the Pim Fortuyn List by preference votes even though he was the last candidate on the list.

Slovakia

In Slovakia, each voter may, in addition to the party, select one to four candidates from the ordered party list. Candidates who are selected by more than 3% of the party's voters are elected (in order of total number of votes) first and only then is the party ordering used. For European elections, voters select two candidates and the candidates must have more than 10% of the total votes to override the party list. In the European election in 2009 three of Slovakia's thirteen MEPs were elected solely by virtue of preference votes (having party-list positions too low to have won otherwise) and only one (Katarína Neveďalová of SMER) was elected solely by virtue of her position on the party list (having fewer preference votes than a number of other candidates who themselves, nevertheless had preferences from fewer than 10 percent of their party's voters).

Sweden

In Sweden, the "most open" list is used, but a person needs to receive 5% of the party's votes for the personal vote to overrule the ordering on the party list.[8] Voting without expressing a preference between individuals is possible, although the parties urge their voters to support the party's prime candidate, to protect them from being beaten by someone ranked lower by the party. The share of voters using the open list option at 2022 Swedish general election was 22.49%.[9]

Most open

The "most open" list system is the one where the absolute number of votes every candidate receives fully determines the "order of election" (the list ranking only possibly serving as a "tiebreaker").

When such a system is used, one could make the case that within every party an additional virtual non-transferable vote election is taking place.

This system is used in all Finnish, Latvian, and Brazilian multiple-seat elections. Since 2001, lists of this "most open" type have also been used in the elections to fill the 96 proportional seats in the 242-member upper house of Japan.

Free lists or panachage

See main article: Panachage. A "free list", more usually called panachage or mixed list, is a variant on the most open list where voters may support candidates on different lists. Candidates are typically elected using either cumulative or block plurality voting. This gives the voters full control over which candidates are elected, not just within a particular party, but even across them. As a result, independents are not forced to support candidates of only one party, and can support candidates across multiple lists, while still ensuring the results are ultimately proportional.[10]

It is used in elections at all levels in Liechtenstein, Luxembourg, and Switzerland, in congressional elections in Ecuador, El Salvador, and Honduras, as well as in local elections in a majority of German states, in French communes with under 1,000 inhabitants, and in Czech municipal elections.

Ballot format

Some ways to operate an open list system when using traditional paper-based voting are as follows:

Use

By country

Some of these states may use other systems in addition to an open list, for example first-past-the-post in individual constituencies. Some countries use open list may only be used in one of the chambers of the legislature.

Africa

Americas

Asia-Pacific

Europe

Partially recognized states

Types

Types of open list systems used in the lower house of the national legislature.[35]

CountryLegislative bodySystemVariation of open listsNumber of votes (for candidates)Apportionment methodElectoral thresholdGovernmental systemNotes
AlbaniaParliament (Kuvendi)Open list party proportional representationd'Hondt method4% nationally or 2.5% in a districtParliamentary republic
ArmeniaNational AssemblyOpen list party proportional representationD'Hondt method5% (parties), 7% (blocs)Parliamentary republicParty lists run-off, but only if necessary to ensure stable majority of 54% if it is not achieved either immediately (one party) or through building a coalition.[36] [37] If a party would win more than 2/3 seats, at least 1/3 seats are distributed to the other parties.

ArubaParliamentOpen list party proportional representation0-1D'Hondt method
AustriaNational CouncilOpen list party proportional representationMore open

14% on the district level (among votes for the candidates party)

1 in each geographic level of candidate listHare quota4%Parliamentary republic
More open

10% on the regional (state) level (among votes for the candidates party)

Hare quota
More open

7% of the on the federal level (among votes for the candidates party)

d'Hondt method
BelgiumChamber of RepresentativesOpen list party proportional representationAs many as there are mandates in the districtD'Hondt method5% (per constitutiency)Constitutional monarchy
Bosnia and HerzegovinaHouse of RepresentativesOpen list party proportional representation0-1Sainte-Laguë methodParliamentary directorial republic
BrazilChamber of DeputiesOpen list party proportional representation0-1D'Hondt method2% distributed in at least 9 Federation Units with at least 1% of the valid votes in each one of themPresidential republic
BulgariaNational AssemblyOpen list party proportional representation0-1Hare quota4%Parliamentary republic
ChileChamber of DeputiesOpen list party proportional representation1
CroatiaOpen list party proportional representation0-15%
CyprusOpen list party proportional representation0-1 for every 4 seats in the district
Czech RepublicOpen list party proportional representation0-45%
Democratic Republic of the CongoParallel voting0-1 to 0-5 depending on number of mandates in the district
DenmarkFolketing (Unicameral legislature)Open list two tier proportional representation with compensating0-12%
East Timor
EcuadorNational CongressOpen list two tiers proportional representation without compensating

As many as there are mandates in the district Panachage allowedSainte-Laguë method
El SalvadorLegislative AssemblyOpen list party proportional representationAs many as there are mandates in the district Panachage allowedD'Hondt method
EstoniaOpen list party proportional representation15%
FijiOpen list party proportional representation1D'Hondt method5%
FinlandOpen list party proportional representation1D'Hondt method
GreeceMajority bonus0-1 to 0-5 depending on number of mandates in the districtLargest remainder (Hare quota)3%Nationwide closed lists and open lists in multi-member districts. The winning party used to receive a majority bonus of 50 seats (out of 300), but this system will be abolished two elections after 2016.[38] In 2020 parliament voted to return to the majority bonus two elections thereafter.[39]
HondurasOpen list party proportional representationAs many as there are mandates in the district Panachage allowedLargest remainder (Hare quota)
IcelandOpen list party proportional representationMay change order of candidates on list or cross out rejected candidatesd'Hondt method
IndonesiaOpen list party proportional representation0-1Sainte-Laguë method4%
KosovoOpen list party proportional representation0-5Sainte-Laguë method
LatviaOpen list party proportional representationMay vote for as many candidates or reject as many candidates as there are on the listSainte-Laguë method5%
LebanonOpen list party proportional representation0-1d'Hondt method
LiechtensteinOpen list party proportional representationAs many as there are mandates in the district8%
LithuaniaParallel voting0-5Largest remainder (Hare quota)5% (parties), 7% (coalitions)
LuxembourgChamber of DeputiesOpen list party proportional representationPanachage (number of votes equal to the number of members elected)May vote for or delete as many candidates as there are mandates in the district Panachage allowedd'Hondt methodNo de jure thresholdParliamentary system
NetherlandsHouse of RepresentativesOpen list party proportional representationMore open(25% of the quota to override the default party-list)0-1d'Hondt methodNo de jure threshold, but an effective threshold of 0.67% (1/150) for a seatParliamentary system
NorwayParliament (Storting)Open list Two tier proportional representation with compensatingDe facto closed list (50% of votes to override)May change order of candidates on list or cross out rejected candidatesSainte-Laguë method4%
PanamaParallel votingAs many as there are mandates in the districtLargest remainder (Hare quota)
PeruOpen list party proportional representation0-2d'Hondt method5%
PolandSejmOpen list party proportional representation1d'Hondt method5% threshold or more for single parties, 8% or more for coalitions or 0% or more for minoritiesParliamentary republic
San MarinoMajority jackpot / Open list party proportional representation1d'Hondt method3.5%If needed to ensure a stable majority, the two best-placed parties participate in a run-off vote to receive a majority bonus.
SlovakiaOpen list party proportional representation0-4Largest remainder (Hare quota)5%
SloveniaOpen list party proportional representationLargest remainder (Droop quota)4%
0-1d'Hondt method4%
Sri LankaParliamentOpen list Two tier proportional representation without compensatingPanachage(up to 3 preference votes)[40] 0-3Hare quota with largest party receives bonus seat de facto d'Hondt method5%(per constituency)Semi-presidential system

?No threshold
SurinameNational AssemblyOpen list party proportional representationMost open0-1d'Hondt methodNo thresholdAssembly-independent republic
SwedenRiksdagOpen list Two tiers proportional representation with compensatingMore open(5% of the party vote to override the default party-list)[41] 0-1Sainte-Laguë method (leveling seats)4% nationally or 12%in a given constituencyParliamentary system
SwitzerlandNational Council (Lower house of national legislature)Open list party proportional representationPanachageMay vote for or delete as many candidates as there are mandates in the district Panachage allowedHagenbach-Bischoff systemNo thresholdSemi-direct democracy under an assembly-independent[42] [43] directorial republic

Notes

CEPPS

External links

Notes and References

  1. Web site: Hvað þurfa margir að strika út mann til að hann færist niður? . Landskjörstjórn . 28 May 2022 . 28 May 2022 . https://web.archive.org/web/20220528204754/https://www.landskjor.is/kosningamal/kosningakerfi/nr/79 . live .
  2. Web site: Helgason . Þorkell . Greining á úthlutun þingsæta eftir alþingiskosningarnar 27. apríl 2013 . Landskjörstjórn . 28 May 2022 . 24 January 2022 . https://web.archive.org/web/20220124090128/https://www.landskjor.is/media/frettir/Greining2013nov.pdf . live .
  3. Web site: Valgloven §7-2, §11-5, §11-10, §11-12 og §6-2 . 2021-06-05 . 2021-06-05 . https://web.archive.org/web/20210605090954/https://lovdata.no/dokument/NL/lov/2002-06-28-57/ . live .
  4. https://www.help.gv.at/Portal.Node/hlpd/public/content/32/Seite.320260.html Vorzugsstimmenvergabe bei einer Nationalratswahl ("Preferential voting in a federal election")
  5. Web site: Zakon o izborima zastupnika u Hrvatski sabor (Act on Election of Representatives to the Croatian Parliament) . hr . August 27, 2018 . August 28, 2018 . https://web.archive.org/web/20180828035834/https://www.zakon.hr/z/355/Zakon-o-izborima-zastupnika-u-Hrvatski-sabor . live .
  6. Web site: IPU PARLINE database: Czech Republic (Poslanecka Snemovna), Electoral system . 2018-08-27 . 2021-02-24 . https://web.archive.org/web/20210224091611/http://archive.ipu.org/parline-e/reports/2083_B.htm . live .
  7. Web site: IPU PARLINE database: INDONESIA (Dewan Perwakilan Rakyat), Electoral system . 2018-08-27 . 2018-10-16 . https://web.archive.org/web/20181016132843/http://archive.ipu.org/parline-e/reports/2147_B.htm . live .
  8. Swedish Election Authority: Elections in Sweden: The way its done (page 16)
  9. https://www.val.se/servicelankar/otherlanguages/englishengelska/electionresults/electionresults2022.4.14c1f613181ed0043d5583f.html 2022 Swedish election results, Section: Voting patterns, Personal votes in Riksdag elections (number), 2022, The Swedish electoral authority
  10. "Open, closed, and free lists", ACE Electoral Knowledge Network
  11. « Voilà comment voter électroniquement avec Smartmatic », video posted on Youtube by the Belgian Federal Interior Ministry
  12. Web site: IPU PARLINE database: DEMOCRATIC REPUBLIC OF THE CONGO (Assemblée nationale), Electoral system . 2018-08-19 . 2021-02-24 . https://web.archive.org/web/20210224070537/http://archive.ipu.org/parline-e/reports/2375_B.htm . live .
  13. Politicians, Parties, and Electoral Systems: Brazil in Comparative Perspective . Mainwaring, Scott . Comparative Politics . October 1991 . 24 . 1 . 21–43 . 10.2307/422200 . 422200 . 2012-08-01 . 2016-05-08 . https://web.archive.org/web/20160508120102/http://kellogg.nd.edu/publications/workingpapers/WPS/141.pdf . live .
  14. Craig Arceneaux, Democratic Latin America, Routledge, 2015 p.339
  15. George Rodriguez, "Voters head to the polls in El Salvador to elect legislators, mayors ", Tico Times, 28 February 2015
  16. "Papeletas para las elecciones 2015 (reproduction of ballot papers and explanation of the new voting system)", Tribunal Supremo Electoral
  17. http://ps.ucdavis.edu/people/mshugart Matthew S. Shugart
  18. "Honduras ", Election Passport
  19. Web site: IPU PARLINE database: PANAMA (Asamblea Nacional), Electoral system . 2018-08-19 . 2022-04-07 . https://web.archive.org/web/20220407064215/http://archive.ipu.org/parline-e/reports/2245_B.htm . live .
  20. Web site: IFES Election Guide | Country Profile: Peru . 2018-08-19 . 2021-04-22 . https://web.archive.org/web/20210422043153/http://www.electionguide.org/countries/id/170/ . live .
  21. "http://archive.ipu.org/parline-e/reports/2299_B.htm "
  22. Web site: Fijan elections office. Electoral decree 2014. 3 July 2014. https://web.archive.org/web/20140714162747/http://www.electionsfiji.gov.fj/wp-content/uploads/2014/03/Electoral-Decree-2014.pdf. 14 July 2014.
  23. [:ja:非拘束名簿式]
  24. Web site: IPU PARLINE database: JORDAN (Majlis Al-Nuwaab), Electoral system . 2018-08-19 . 2018-08-19 . https://web.archive.org/web/20180819214231/http://archive.ipu.org/parline-e/reports/2163_B.htm . live .
  25. Web site: Lebanon to hold parliamentary elections in May 2018. 23 June 2017. 14 June 2017 . 18 June 2018. https://web.archive.org/web/20180618075837/https://gulfnews.com/news/mena/lebanon/lebanon-to-hold-parliamentary-elections-in-may-2018-1.2043638. live.
  26. Web site: 2020. Broshurë Informative mbi proceset zgjedhore Parlamentare dhe Lokale në Shqipëri, mbi partitë politike, legjislacionin, rekomandimet e OSBE/ODIHR (1991-2020) . Information Booklet on Parliamentary and Local Electoral Processes in Albania, on Political Parties, Legislation, OSCE / ODIHR Recommendations (1991-2020) . live. https://web.archive.org/web/20210201235940/http://isp.com.al/wp-content/uploads/2020/11/ISP-%E2%80%93-Broshure-informative-mbi-zgjedhjet-ne-Shqiperi-1991-2020.pdf. 1 February 2021. Instituti i Studimeve Politike (ISP). sq.
  27. Web site: Armenia's New Electoral Code: Open vs. Closed Party Lists and Other Considerations . 12 July 2018 . August 24, 2022 . August 24, 2022 . https://web.archive.org/web/20220824144607/https://evnreport.com/politics/armenias-new-electoral-code-open-vs-closed-party-lists-and-other-considerations/ . live .
  28. Web site: Izborni zakon BiH, članovi 9.5 i 9.8 . September 2, 2012 . March 7, 2021 . https://web.archive.org/web/20210307223904/http://www.izbori.ba/Documents/documents/ZAKONI/POIZpw110508.pdf . live .
  29. Web site: Report on Proportional Electoral Systems: the Allocation of Seats inside the Lists (open/closed lists) . Venice Commission . March 23, 2015 . January 24, 2023.
  30. Web site: Zakon o izborima zastupnika u Hrvatski sabor (Act on Election of Representatives to the Croatian Parliament) . hr . April 8, 2018 . April 9, 2018 . https://web.archive.org/web/20180409044144/https://www.zakon.hr/z/355/Zakon-o-izborima-zastupnika-u-Hrvatski-sabor . live .
  31. Pork-Barrel Politics in Postwar Italy, 1953-94 . Miriam A. Golden . Lucio Picci . American Journal of Political Science . April 2008 . 52 . 2 . 268–289 . 10.1111/j.1540-5907.2007.00312.x . 2012-08-01 . 2021-03-01 . https://web.archive.org/web/20210301132951/https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/5626/1/MPRA_paper_5626.pdf . live .
  32. Web site: IFES Election Guide | Country Profile: Lithuania . 2018-08-19 . 2018-08-20 . https://web.archive.org/web/20180820005703/http://www.electionguide.org/countries/id/125/ . live .
  33. Web site: Electoral Systems in Europe: An Overview . European Centre for Parliamentary Research and Documentation . European Parliament in Brussels . October 2000 . July 6, 2012 . https://web.archive.org/web/20130509064043/https://ecprd.secure.europarl.europa.eu/ecprd/getfile.do;jsessionid=3b490694614cde33796973863f72c657?id=5063 . May 9, 2013 .
  34. https://www.kyivpost.com/ukraine-politics/ukrinform-ukrainian-parliament-adopts-electoral-code.html UkrInform: Ukrainian parliament adopts Electoral Code
  35. https://www.idea.int/sites/default/files/publications/open-list-proportional-representation.pdf
  36. Web site: Armenia, Parliamentary Elections, 2 April 2017: Needs Assessment Mission Report . 2022-05-30 . . en.
  37. Web site: DocumentView . www.arlis.am.
  38. News: 2016-07-21 . Greek MPs approve end to bonus seats, lower voting age . 2019-06-22 . Reuters . en.
  39. Web site: Parliament votes to change election law Kathimerini . 2020-01-25 . www.ekathimerini.com . en.
  40. Web site: August 4, 2020 . Sri Lanka electors can vote for one party, three preferences in 2020 general elections: polls chief . EconomyNext.
  41. Swedish Election Authority: Elections in Sweden: The way its done (page 16)
  42. Shugart . Matthew Søberg . December 2005 . Semi-Presidential Systems: Dual Executive And Mixed Authority Patterns . French Politics . 3 . 3 . 323–351 . 10.1057/palgrave.fp.8200087 . 73642272 . free.
  43. Elgie . Robert . 2016 . Government Systems, Party Politics, and Institutional Engineering in the Round . Insight Turkey . 18 . 4 . 79–92 . 1302-177X . 26300453.