Political economy explained

Political economy is a branch of political science and economics studying economic systems (e.g. markets and national economies) and their governance by political systems (e.g. law, institutions, and government).[1] [2] [3] Widely studied phenomena within the discipline are systems such as labour markets and financial markets, as well as phenomena such as growth, distribution, inequality, and trade, and how these are shaped by institutions, laws, and government policy. Originating in the 16th century, it is the precursor to the modern discipline of economics.[4] [5] Political economy in its modern form is considered an interdisciplinary field, drawing on theory from both political science and modern economics.

Political economy originated within 16th century western moral philosophy, with theoretical works exploring the administration of states' wealth; "political" signifying the Greek word polity and "economy" signifying the Greek word ; household management. The earliest works of political economy are usually attributed to the British scholars Adam Smith, Thomas Malthus, and David Ricardo, although they were preceded by the work of the French physiocrats, such as François Quesnay (1694–1774) and Anne-Robert-Jacques Turgot (1727–1781).[6]

In the late 19th century, the term "economics" gradually began to replace the term "political economy" with the rise of mathematical modeling coinciding with the publication of an influential textbook by Alfred Marshall in 1890.[7] Earlier, William Stanley Jevons, a proponent of mathematical methods applied to the subject, advocated economics for brevity and with the hope of the term becoming "the recognised name of a science".[8] [9] Citation measurement metrics from Google Ngram Viewer indicate that use of the term "economics" began to overshadow "political economy" around roughly 1910, becoming the preferred term for the discipline by 1920.[10] According to economist Clara Mattei, this shift was driven by the increasing consensus of classical liberalism as natural-law; and persisted despite evidence to the contrary during the First World War.[11] Today, the term "economics" usually refers to the narrow study of the economy absent other political and social considerations while the term "political economy" represents a distinct and competing approach.

Etymology

Originally, political economy meant the study of the conditions under which production or consumption within limited parameters was organized in nation-states. In that way, political economy expanded the emphasis on economics, which comes from the Greek oikos (meaning "home") and nomos (meaning "law" or "order"). Political economy was thus meant to express the laws of production of wealth at the state level, quite like economics concerns putting home to order. The phrase économie politique (translated in English to "political economy") first appeared in France in 1615 with the well-known book by Antoine de Montchrétien, Traité de l'economie politique. Other contemporary scholars attribute the roots of this study to the 13th Century Tunisian Arab Historian and Sociologist, Ibn Khaldun, for his work on making the distinction between "profit" and "sustenance", in modern political economy terms, surplus and that required for the reproduction of classes respectively. He also calls for the creation of a science to explain society and goes on to outline these ideas in his major work, the Muqaddimah. In Al-Muqaddimah Khaldun states, "Civilization and its well-being, as well as business prosperity, depend on productivity and people's efforts in all directions in their own interest and profit" – seen as a modern precursor to Classical Economic thought.

Leading on from this, the French physiocrats were the first major exponents of political economy,[12] although the intellectual responses of Adam Smith, John Stuart Mill, David Ricardo, Henry George and Karl Marx to the physiocrats generally receive much greater attention.[13] The world's first professorship in political economy was established in 1754 at the University of Naples Federico II in southern Italy. The Neapolitan philosopher Antonio Genovesi was the first tenured professor. In 1763, Joseph von Sonnenfels was appointed a Political Economy chair at the University of Vienna, Austria. Thomas Malthus, in 1805, became England's first professor of political economy, at the East India Company College, Haileybury, Hertfordshire. At present, political economy refers to different yet related approaches to studying economic and related behaviours, ranging from the combination of economics with other fields to the use of different, fundamental assumptions challenging earlier economic assumptions.

Current approaches

Political economy most commonly refers to interdisciplinary studies drawing upon economics, sociology and political science in explaining how political institutions, the political environment, and the economic systemcapitalist, socialist, communist, or mixed—influence each other.[14] The Journal of Economic Literature classification codes associate political economy with three sub-areas: (1) the role of government and/or class and power relationships in resource allocation for each type of economic system;[15] (2) international political economy, which studies the economic impacts of international relations;[16] and (3) economic models of political or exploitative class processes.[17] Within the field of political science, there is generally a distinction between international political economy (studied by international relations scholars) and comparative political economy (studied by comparative politics scholars).

Public choice theory is a microfoundations theory closely intertwined with political economy. Both approaches model voters, politicians and bureaucrats as behaving in mainly self-interested ways, in contrast to a view, ascribed to earlier mainstream economists, of government officials trying to maximize individual utilities from some kind of social welfare function.[18] As such, economists and political scientists often associate political economy with approaches using rational-choice assumptions,[19] especially in game theory[20] and in examining phenomena beyond economics' standard remit, such as government failure and complex decision making in which context the term "positive political economy" is common.[21] Other "traditional" topics include analysis of such public policy issues as economic regulation,[22] monopoly, rent-seeking, market protection,[23] institutional corruption[24] and distributional politics.[25] Empirical analysis includes the influence of elections on the choice of economic policy, determinants and forecasting models of electoral outcomes, the political business cycles,[26] central-bank independence and the politics of excessive deficits.[27] An interesting example would be the publication in 1954 of the first manual of Political Economy in the Soviet Union, edited by Lev Gatovsky, which mixed the classic theoretical approach of the time with the soviet political discourse.[28]

A rather recent focus has been put on modeling economic policy and political institutions concerning interactions between agents and economic and political institutions,[29] including the seeming discrepancy of economic policy and economist's recommendations through the lens of transaction costs.[30] From the mid-1990s, the field has expanded, in part aided by new cross-national data sets allowing tests of hypotheses on comparative economic systems and institutions.[31] Topics have included the breakup of nations,[32] the origins and rate of change of political institutions in relation to economic growth,[33] development,[34] financial markets and regulation,[35] the importance of institutions,[36] backwardness,[37] reform[38] and transition economies,[39] the role of culture, ethnicity and gender in explaining economic outcomes,[40] macroeconomic policy,[41] the environment,[42] fairness[43] and the relation of constitutions to economic policy, theoretical[44] and empirical.[45]

Other important landmarks in the development of political economy include:

Related disciplines

Because political economy is not a unified discipline, there are studies using the term that overlap in subject matter, but have radically different perspectives:[57]

Journals

See also

References

External links

Notes and References

  1. Book: Bladen . Vincent . An Introduction to Political Economy . 2016 . University of Toronto Press . 978-1442632103 . 1013947543 . Vincent Bladen.
  2. Book: Mill, John Stuart, 1806–1873. . Principles of political economy : with some of their applications to social philosophy . 2009 . Bibliolife . 978-1116761184 . 663099414.
  3. Web site: political economy Britannica . 2022-05-15 . www.britannica.com . en . 2019-12-14 . https://web.archive.org/web/20191214194856/https://www.britannica.com/topic/political-economy . live .
  4. Web site: economics Definition, History, Examples, Types, & Facts Britannica . 2022-05-15 . www.britannica.com . en . 2015-06-15 . https://web.archive.org/web/20150615062550/https://www.britannica.com/topic/economics . live .
  5. Web site: Weingast . Barry R. . Wittman . Donald A. . 2011-07-07 . Overview Of Political Economy . 2022-05-15 . The Oxford Handbook of Political Science . en . 10.1093/oxfordhb/9780199604456.013.0038 . 2022-05-15 . https://web.archive.org/web/20220515165024/https://www.oxfordhandbooks.com/view/10.1093/oxfordhb/9780199604456.001.0001/oxfordhb-9780199604456-e-038 . live .
  6. Steiner (2003), pp. 61–62
  7. Marshall, Alfred. (1890) Principles of Economics.
  8. Jevons, W. Stanley. The Theory of Political Economy, 1879, 2nd ed. p. xiv.
  9. Groenwegen, Peter. (1987 [2008]). "'political economy' and 'economics'", , v. 3, pp. 905–906. [Pp. 904–07.]
  10. Mark Robbins (2016) "Why we need political economy," Policy Options, http://policyoptions.irpp.org/magazines/january-2017/why-we-need-political-economy/
  11. Mattei, Clara. The Capital Order, 2022
  12. Bertholet. Auguste. 2020-05-27. The intellectual origins of Mirabeau. History of European Ideas. 47. 91–96. 10.1080/01916599.2020.1763745. 219747599. 0191-6599.
  13. Web site: What is Political Economy?. Political Economy, Athabasca University. en-CA. 2022-02-06. 2022-02-07. https://web.archive.org/web/20220207020919/https://www.athabascau.ca/humanities-and-social-sciences/resources/ba-poec-what-is-political-economy.html. live.
  14. Weingast, Barry R., and Donald Wittman, ed., 2008. The Oxford Handbook of Political Economy. Oxford UP. Description and preview.
  15. At JEL: P as in JEL Classification Codes Guide, drilled to at each economic-system link.
    For example:
       • Brandt, Loren, and Thomas G. Rawski (2008). "Chinese economic reforms," The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract.
       • Helsley, Robert W. (2008). "urban political economy," The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract.
  16. At JEL: F5 as drilled to in JEL Classification Codes Guide .
    For example:
       • Gilpin, Robert (2001), Global Political Economy: Understanding the International Economic Order, Princeton. Description and ch. 1, " The New Global Economic Order" link.
       • Mitra, Devashish (2008). "trade policy, political economy of," The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract.
  17. At JEL: D72 and JEL: D74 with context for its usage in JEL Classification Codes Guide, drilled to at JEL: D7.
  18. Tullock, Gordon ([1987] 2008). "public choice," The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Abstract .
       • Arrow, Kenneth J. (1963). Social Choice and Individual Values, 2nd ed., ch. VIII, sect. 2, The Social Decision Process, pp. 106–08.
  19. Lohmann, Susanne (2008). "rational choice and political science," The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract.
  20. Shubik, Martin (1981). "Game Theory Models and Methods in Political Economy," in K. Arrow and M. Intriligator, ed., Handbook of Mathematical Economics, Elsevier, v. 1, pp. 285-330.
       • _____ (1984). A Game-Theoretic Approach to Political Economy. MIT Press. Description and review extract.
       • _____ (1999). Political Economy, Oligopoly and Experimental Games: The Selected Essays of Martin Shubik, v. 1, Edward Elgar. Description and contents of Part I, Political Economy.
       • Peter C. Ordeshook (1990). "The Emerging Discipline of Political Economy," ch. 1 in Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, Cambridge, pp. 9–30.
       • _____ (1986). Game Theory and Political Theory, Cambridge.Description and preview.
  21. Alt, James E.; Shepsle, Kenneth (eds.) (1990), Perspectives on Positive Political Economy (Cambridge [UK]; New York: Cambridge University Press). Description and content links and preview.
  22. Rose, N. L. (2001). "Regulation, Political Economy of," International Encyclopedia of the Social & Behavioral Sciences, pp. 12967–12970. Abstract.
  23. [Anne O. Krueger|Krueger, Anne O.]
  24. • Bose, Niloy. "corruption and economic growth," The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Online, 2nd Edition, 2010. Abstract.
       • Rose-Ackerman, Susan (2008). "bribery," The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract.
  25. Becker, Gary S. (1983). "A Theory of Competition among Pressure Groups for Political Influence," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98(3), pp. 371–400.
       • Weingast, Barry R., Kenneth A. Shepsle, and Christopher Johnsen (1981). "The Political Economy of Benefits and Costs: A Neoclassical Approach to Distributive Politics," Journal of Political Economy, 89(4), pp. 642–664.
       • Breyer, Friedrich (1994). "The Political Economy of Intergenerational Redistribution," European Journal of Political Economy, 10(1), pp. 61–84. Abstract.
       • Williamson, Oliver E. (1995). "The Politics and Economics of Redistribution and Inefficiency," Greek Economic Review, December, 17, pp. 115–136, reprinted in Williamson (1996), The Mechanisms of Governance, Oxford University Press, ch. 8, pp. 195–218.
       • Krusell, Per, and José-Víctor Ríos-Rull (1999). "On the Size of U.S. Government: Political Economy in the Neoclassical Growth Model," American Economic Review, 89(5), pp. 1156–1181.
       • Galasso, Vincenzo, and Paola Profeta (2002). "The Political Economy of Social Security: A Survey," European Journal of Political Economy, 18(1), pp. 1–29.
  26. • Drazen, Allan (2008). "Political business cycles," The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract.
       • Nordhaus, William D. (1989). "Alternative Approaches to the Political Business Cycle," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, (2), pp. 1 –68.
  27. Buchanan, James M. (2008). "public debt," The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract.
       • Alesina, Alberto, and Roberto Perotti (1995). "The Political Economy of Budget Deficits," IMF Staff Papers, 42(1), pp. 1–31.
  28. Book: Political Economy: A Textbook issued by the Economics Institute of the Academy of Sciences of the U.S.S.R . K.V. Ostrovityanov; D.T. Shepilov; L.A. Leontyev; I.D. Laptev; I.I. Kuzminov; L.M. Gatovsky; P.F. Yudin; A.I. Pashkov; V. N. Starovsky . 1954 . Economics Institute of the Academy of Sciences of the U.S.S.R . 1st . Moscow . Marxists Internet Archive . 2014 . ru . Political Economy: A Textbook issued by the Economics Institute of the Academy of Sciences of the U.S.S.R.
  29. Timothy, Besley (2007). Principled Agents?: The Political Economy of Good Government, Oxford. Description.
       • _____ and Torsten Persson (2008). "political institutions, economic approaches to," The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract.
       • North, Douglass C. (1986). "The New Institutional Economics," Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 142(1), pp. 230–237.
       • _____ (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance, in the Political Economy of Institutions and Decisions series. Cambridge. Description and preview.
       • Ostrom, Elinor (1990). Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. Cambridge University Press. Description and preview links. .
       • _____ (2010). "Beyond Markets and States: Polycentric Governance of Complex Economic Systems," American Economic Review, 100(3), pp. 641–672 .
  30. [Avinash Dixit|Dixit, Avinash]
  31. Beck, Thorsten et al. (2001). "New Tools in Comparative Political Economy: The Database of Political Institutions," World Bank Economic Review,15(1), pp. 165–176.
  32. Bolton, Patrick, and Gérard Roland (1997). "The Breakup of Nations: A Political Economy Analysis," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(4), pp. 1057–1090.
  33. Alesina, Alberto, and Roberto Perotti (1994). "The Political Economy of Growth: A Critical Survey of the Recent Literature," World Bank Economic Review, 8(3), pp. 351–371.
  34. Keefer, Philip (2004). "What Does Political Economy Tell Us about Economic Development and Vice Versa?" Annual Review of Political Science, 7, pp. 247–272. PDF.
  35. Perotti, Enrico (2014). "The Political Economy of Finance", in"Capitalism and Society" Vol. 9, No. 1, Article 1 https://ssrn.com/abstract=2427842
  36. "Chang, H. J. (2002). Breaking the Mould – An Institutionalist Political Economy Alternative to the Neo-Liberal Theory of the Market and State", in "Cambridge Journal of Economics", 26(5), http://www.unrisd.org/80256B3C005BCCF9/(httpAuxPages)/44552A491D461D0180256B5E003CAFCC/$file/chang.pdf
  37. [Daron Acemoglu|Acemoglu, Daron]
  38. • Mukand, Sharun W. (2008). "policy reform, political economy of," The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract.
       • Sturzenegger, Federico, and Mariano Tommasi (1998). The Polítical Economy of Reform, MIT Press. Description and chapter-preview links.
  39. Roland, Gérard (2002), "The Political Economy of Transition," Journal of Economic Perspectives, 16(1), pp. 29–50.
       • _____ (2000). Transition and Economics: Politics, Markets, and Firms, MIT Press. Description and preview.
       • Manor, James (1999). The Political Economy of Democratic Decentralization, The World Bank. . Description.
  40. [Alberto Alesina|Alesina, Alberto F.]
  41. Drazen, Allan (2000). Political Economy in Macroeconomics, Princeton. Description & ch. 1-preview link., and review extract.
  42. • Dietz, Simon, Jonathan Michie, and Christine Oughton (2011). Political Economy of the Environment An Interdisciplinary Approach, Routledge. Description and preview.
       • Banzhaf, H. Spencer, ed. (2012). The Political Economy of Environmental Justice Stanford U.P. Description and contents links.
       • Gleeson, Brendan, and Nicholas Low (1998). Justice, Society and Nature An Exploration of Political Ecology, Routledge. Description and preview.
       • John S. Dryzek, 2000. Rational Ecology: Environment and Political Economy, Blackburn Press. B&N description.
       • Barry, John 2001. "Justice, Nature and Political Economy," Economy and Society, 30(3), pp. 381–394.
       • Boyce, James K. (2002). The Political Economy of the Environment, Edward Elgar. Description.
  43. •Zajac, Edward E. (1996). Political Economy of Fairness, MIT Press Description and chapter-preview links.
       • Thurow, Lester C. (1980). The Zero-sum Society: Distribution and the Possibilities For Economic Change, Penguin. Description and preview.
  44. Persson, Torsten, and Guido Tabellini (2000). Political Economics: Explaining Economic Policy, MIT Press. Review extract, description and chapter-preview links.
       • Laffont, Jean-Jacques (2000). Incentives and Political Economy, Oxford. Description.
       • Acemoglu, Daron (2003). "Why Not a Political Coase Theorem? Social Conflict, Commitment, and Politics," Journal of Comparative Economics, 31(4), pp. 620–652.
  45. Persson, Torsten, and Guido Tabellini (2003). The Economic Effects Of Constitutions, Munich Lectures in Economics. MIT Press. Description and preview, and review extract.
  46. Mayer, Charles S. (1987). In Search of Stability: Explorations in Historical Political Economy, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp. 3–6. Description and scrollable preview. Cambridge.
  47. cf: Baker, David (2006). "The political economy of fascism: Myth or reality, or myth and reality?", New Political Economy, 11(2), pp. 227–250.
  48. Brown. Chris. July 1999. Susan Strange—a critical appreciation. Review of International Studies. en. 25. 3. 531–535. 10.1017/S0260210599005318. 1469-9044. free.
  49. Cohen, Benjamin J. "The transatlantic divide: Why are American and British IPE so different?", Review of International Political Economy, Vol. 14, No. 2, May 2007.
  50. McCoy, Drew R. "The Elusive Republic: Political Economy in Jeffersonian America", Chapel Hill, University of North Carolina.
  51. Law and the Political Economy of the World. Kennedy. David. 2013. Leiden Journal of International Law. 26. 7–48. 10.1017/S0922156512000635. 153363066. December 24, 2015. March 4, 2016. https://web.archive.org/web/20160304193957/http://www.law.harvard.edu/faculty/dkennedy/publications/PoliticalEconomy.pdf. live.
  52. Book: Haskell, John D.. Research Handbook on Political Economy and Law. Edward Elgar. 2015. 978-1781005347.
  53. Capital in the Twenty-First Century, Harvard University Press, 2014,
  54. Web site: About Political Economy | Department of Political Economy | King's College London . 2019-03-04 . 2019-03-06 . https://web.archive.org/web/20190306044311/https://www.kcl.ac.uk/political-economy/about/index . live .
  55. Web site: 2012-11-05 . Why Political Economy? . 2022-04-26 . SPERI . en-GB . 2022-08-16 . https://web.archive.org/web/20220816215312/http://speri.dept.shef.ac.uk/2012/11/05/political-economy/ . live .
  56. Web site: Home . The Political Economy UK Group . 2019-03-04 . 2019-03-06 . https://web.archive.org/web/20190306044246/https://www.poleconuk.net/ . live .
  57. Encyclopedia: political economy. Encyclopedia Britannica. 2017-06-15. en.
  58. Hirth, Kenneth G. 1996. Political Economy and Archaeology: Perspectives on Exchange and Production. Journal of Archaeological Research, 4(3):203–239.
  59. May. Robert M.. Levin. Simon A.. Sugihara. George. Ecology for bankers. Nature. 451. February 21, 2008. 7181. 893–895. 10.1038/451893a. 18288170. free.