Non-tax revenue explained
Non-tax revenue or non-tax receipts are government revenue not generated from taxes.
Examples
- Rents, concessions, and royalties from private firms
- often from leases for developing natural resources on public land or fisheries in territorial waters
- User fees collected in exchange for the use of many public services and facilities. Tolls charged for the use of toll roads are an example
- Fees for the granting or issuance of permits or licenses. Examples include:
- vehicle registration plate permits or vehicle registration fees
- watercraft registration fees
- building fees
- driver's licenses
- hunting and fishing licenses
- fees for professional licensing
- fees for visas or passports
- fees for demolition, rezoning, and land grading
- less often, fines for increasing stormwater runoff, destroying native vegetation, or cutting-down healthy trees
- Fines collected and assets forfeited as a penalty. Examples include parking fines, court costs levied on criminal offenders, and civil forfeiture
- Aid from abroad (foreign aid)
- Aid from another level of government (intragovernmental aid) or from equalization payments
- Loans, or other borrowing, from monetary funds and/or other governments
- Tribute or indemnities paid by a weaker state to a stronger one, often as a condition of peace after suffering military defeat. The war reparations paid by the defeated Central Powers after the First World War offer a well-known example.
- Revenue from profitable state-owned enterprises
- Revenue from investment funds, sovereign wealth funds, or endowments
- Revenue from sales of state-owned assets
- Donations and voluntary contributions to the state
Global distribution and volume
Vis-à-vis tax revenues, much less academic study has been conducted into the volume and distribution of non-tax revenues,[1] although the most significant forms — oil and natural gas revenues and foreign aid — have been extensively studied since Hossein Mahdavy’s seminal 1970 analysis of the Imperial State of Iran.[2]
In 2009, Farhan Zainulabideen and Zafar Iqbal estimated non-tax revenues to comprise a quarter of total global government revenue.[3] Three years later, Christian von Haldenwang and Maksym Ivanyna produced a higher estimate of around 31 percent.
Twenty-first century studies show that non-tax revenue in petrostates can reach up to 80 percent of Gross Domestic Product and over 90 percent of total government revenue.[4] In resource-poor nations — excluding those gaining strategic rents due to geography or perceived need for aid — non-tax revenues are typically around 10 percent of total government revenue.
Volatility
Non-tax revenues fluctuate much more from one year to another than taxes — three times as much in the European Union,[5] and slightly less than that for the globe as a whole.[6] Many countries in Africa can report changes in non-tax revenue of over 35 percent from one year to another due to variations in the price of their natural resources.[7]
Their value is correlated with changing economic circumstances, repayments and interest on loans may be renegotiated, a record fine in the field of competition can significantly vary the profits of fines and penalties. Moreover, some years are marked by exceptional events: for example, in France in 2012, the sale of "4G" radio frequencies resulted in the collection of nearly €1.3 billion in non-tax revenues.[8]
Effects
The presence of large non-tax revenues — invariably from non-renewable natural resources, foreign aid, or strategic rents like those associated with the Suez Canal — has been shown to make democratisation much less possible.[4] This is generally argued to be because large non-tax revenues weaken the links between state and society and facilitate government investment in repression and patronage,[9] and also because the presence of large non-tax revenues leads to less redistribution of wealth.[1] For instance, it has been calculated that foreign aid has reduced tax revenue in sub-Saharan Africa by ten percent.[10]
Notes and References
- Morrison . Kevin M. . Oil, Non-Tax Revenue, and the Redistributional Foundations of Regime Stability . Duke University. Duke University Seminar on Global Governance and Democracy. October 24, 2006.
- See Book: Mahdavy, Hossein. 1970. The Patterns and Problems of Economic Development in a Rentier Stare: The Case of Iran. Michael A.. Cook. Studies in Economic History of the Middle East. . London.
- Zainulabideen. Farhan. Iqbal . Zafar. Taxation and Good Governance and the Influence of Non-Tax Revenues on a Polity: The Pakistani Experience . Policy Perspectives. July–December 2009. 6. 2. 73-98.
- Prichard. Wilson. Salardi. Paola. Segal . Paul . Taxation, non-tax revenue and democracy: New evidence using new cross-country data . World Development . September 2018 . 109 . 295-312.
- Mourre. Gilles. Reut. Adriana. Non-tax revenue in the European Union: A source of fiscal risk?. Policy Watch. 7 June 2018. 26. 198-223.
- Ossowski. Rolando. Gonzáles. Alberto. Inter-American Development Bank. 2012. Manna from heaven: The impact of nonrenewable resource revenues on other revenues of resource exporters in Latin America and the Caribbean. 17.
- OECD. 2021. Revenue Statistics in Africa, 1990-2019. Non-Tax Revenue Trends, 2000-2019. 103.
- Web site: Les recettes non fiscales . Fourum dela performance . https://web.archive.org/web/20170106230906/http://www.performance-publique.budget.gouv.fr/budget-comptes-etat/budget-etat/approfondir/recettes-etat/recettes-non-fiscales#.XpszoNMzZ0t . 6 January 2017.
- Ross. Michael. Does Oil Hinder Democracy. 2001. World Politics. 53. 3. 325-361.
- Book: Bräutigam. Deborah A.. Taxation and State-Building in Developing Countries: Capacity and Consent. Cambridge. Cambridge University Press. 2008. 18-19.