In portfolio theory, a mutual fund separation theorem, mutual fund theorem, or separation theorem is a theorem stating that, under certain conditions, any investor's optimal portfolio can be constructed by holding each of certain mutual funds in appropriate ratios, where the number of mutual funds is smaller than the number of individual assets in the portfolio. Here a mutual fund refers to any specified benchmark portfolio of the available assets. There are two advantages of having a mutual fund theorem. First, if the relevant conditions are met, it may be easier (or lower in transactions costs) for an investor to purchase a smaller number of mutual funds than to purchase a larger number of assets individually. Second, from a theoretical and empirical standpoint, if it can be assumed that the relevant conditions are indeed satisfied, then implications for the functioning of asset markets can be derived and tested.
Portfolios can be analyzed in a mean-variance framework, with every investor holding the portfolio with the lowest possible return variance consistent with that investor's chosen level of expected return (called a minimum-variance portfolio), if the returns on the assets are jointly elliptically distributed, including the special case in which they are jointly normally distributed.[1] [2] Under mean-variance analysis, it can be shown[3] that every minimum-variance portfolio given a particular expected return (that is, every efficient portfolio) can be formed as a combination of any two efficient portfolios. If the investor's optimal portfolio has an expected return that is between the expected returns on two efficient benchmark portfolios, then that investor's portfolio can be characterized as consisting of positive quantities of the two benchmark portfolios.
To see two-fund separation in a context in which no risk-free asset is available, using matrix algebra, let
\sigma2
\mu
r
X
W
1
Minimize
\sigma2
subject to
XTr=\mu
and
XT1=W
where the superscript
T
\sigma2=XTVX,
V
L=XTVX+2λ(\mu-XTr)+2η(W-XT1),
with Lagrange multipliers
λ
η
X
X
λ
η
X
λ
η
λ
η
X
Xopt=
W | |
\Delta |
[(rTV-1r)V-11-(1TV-1r)V-1r]+
\mu | |
\Delta |
[(1TV-11)V-1r-(rTV-11)V-11]
where
\Delta=(rTV-1r)(1TV-11)-(rTV-11)2>0.
For simplicity this can be written more compactly as
Xopt=\alphaW+\beta\mu
where
\alpha
\beta
\mu1
\mu2
opt | |
X | |
1 |
=\alphaW+\beta\mu1
and
opt | |
X | |
2 |
=\alphaW+\beta\mu2.
The optimal portfolio at arbitrary
\mu3
opt | |
X | |
1 |
opt | |
X | |
2 |
opt | |
X | |
3 |
=\alphaW+\beta\mu3=
\mu3-\mu2 | |
\mu1-\mu2 |
opt | |
X | |
1 |
+
\mu1-\mu3 | |
\mu1-\mu2 |
opt. | |
X | |
2 |
This equation proves the two-fund separation theorem for mean-variance analysis. For a geometric interpretation, see the Markowitz bullet.
If a risk-free asset is available, then again a two-fund separation theorem applies; but in this case one of the "funds" can be chosen to be a very simple fund containing only the risk-free asset, and the other fund can be chosen to be one which contains zero holdings of the risk-free asset. (With the risk-free asset referred to as "money", this form of the theorem is referred to as the monetary separation theorem.) Thus mean-variance efficient portfolios can be formed simply as a combination of holdings of the risk-free asset and holdings of a particular efficient fund that contains only risky assets. The derivation above does not apply, however, since with a risk-free asset the above covariance matrix of all asset returns,
V
Minimize
\sigma2
subject to
T1)r | |
(W-X | |
f |
+XTr=\mu,
where
rf
X
r
(W-XT1)
\sigma2=XTVX
V
Xopt=
(\mu-Wrf) | |||||||||
|
V-1(r-1rf).
Of course this equals a zero vector if
\mu=Wrf
\mu=\tfrac{WrTV-1
TV | |
(r-1r | |
f)}{1 |
-1(r-1rf)}
X*=
W | |
1TV-1(r-1rf) |
V-1(r-1rf).
It can also be shown (analogously to the demonstration in the above two-mutual-fund case) that every portfolio's risky asset vector (that is,
Xopt
\mu
If investors have hyperbolic absolute risk aversion (HARA) (including the power utility function, logarithmic function and the exponential utility function), separation theorems can be obtained without the use of mean-variance analysis. For example, David Cass and Joseph Stiglitz[4] showed in 1970 that two-fund monetary separation applies if all investors have HARA utility with the same exponent as each other.[5]
More recently, in the dynamic portfolio optimization model of Çanakoğlu and Özekici,[6] the investor's level of initial wealth (the distinguishing feature of investors) does not affect the optimal composition of the risky part of the portfolio. A similar result is given by Schmedders.[7]