Discrete fixed-point theorem explained

In discrete mathematics, a discrete fixed-point is a fixed-point for functions defined on finite sets, typically subsets of the integer grid

Zn

.

Discrete fixed-point theorems were developed by Iimura,[1] Murota and Tamura,[2] Chen and Deng[3] and others. Yang[4] provides a survey.

Basic concepts

Continuous fixed-point theorems often require a continuous function. Since continuity is not meaningful for functions on discrete sets, it is replaced by conditions such as a direction-preserving function. Such conditions imply that the function does not change too drastically when moving between neighboring points of the integer grid. There are various direction-preservation conditions, depending on whether neighboring points are considered points of a hypercube (HGDP), of a simplex (SGDP) etc. See the page on direction-preserving function for definitions.

Continuous fixed-point theorems often require a convex set. The analogue of this property for discrete sets is an integrally-convex set.

A fixed point of a discrete function f is defined exactly as for continuous functions: it is a point x for which f(x)=x.

For functions on discrete sets

We focus on functions

f:X\toRn

, where the domain X is a nonempty subset of the Euclidean space

Rn

. ch(X) denotes the convex hull of X.

Iimura-Murota-Tamura theorem: If X is a finite integrally-convex subset of

Zn

, and

f:X\toch(X)

is a hypercubic direction-preserving (HDP) function, then f has a fixed-point.

Chen-Deng theorem: If X is a finite subset of

Rn

, and

f:X\toch(X)

is simplicially direction-preserving (SDP), then f has a fixed-point.

Yang's theorems:

Zn

,

f:X\toRn

is simplicially gross direction preserving (SGDP), and for all x in X there exists some g(x)>0 such that

x+g(x)f(x)\inch(X)

, then f has a zero point.

Zn

, with minimum point a and maximum point b,

f:X\toRn

is SGDP, and for any x in X:

fi(x1,\ldots,xi-1,ai,xi+1,\ldots,xn)\leq0

and

fi(x1,\ldots,xi-1,bi,xi+1,\ldots,xn)\geq0

, then f has a zero point. This is a discrete analogue of the Poincaré–Miranda theorem. It is a consequence of the previous theorem.

Zn

, and

f:X\toch(X)

is such that

f(x)-x

is SGDP, then f has a fixed-point.[5] This is a discrete analogue of the Brouwer fixed-point theorem.

Zn

,

f:X\toRn

is bounded and

f(x)-x

is SGDP, then f has a fixed-point (this follows easily from the previous theorem by taking X to be a subset of

Zn

that bounds f).

Zn

,

F:X\to2X

a point-to-set mapping, and for all x in X:

F(x)=ch(F(x))\capZn

, and there is a function f such that

f(x)\inch(F(x))

and

f(x)-x

is SGDP, then there is a point y in X such that

y\inF(y)

. This is a discrete analogue of the Kakutani fixed-point theorem, and the function f is an analogue of a continuous selection function.

Zn

, and it is also symmetric in the sense that x is in X iff -x is in X. If

f:X\toRn

is SGDP w.r.t. a weakly-symmetric triangulation of ch(X) (in the sense that if s is a simplex on the boundary of the triangulation iff -s is), and

f(x)f(-y)\leq0

for every pair of simplicially-connected points x, y in the boundary of ch(X), then f has a zero point.

For discontinuous functions on continuous sets

Discrete fixed-point theorems are closely related to fixed-point theorems on discontinuous functions. These, too, use the direction-preservation condition instead of continuity.

Herings-Laan-Talman-Yang fixed-point theorem:[6]

Let X be a non-empty convex compact subset of

Rn

. Let f: XX be a locally gross direction preserving (LGDP) function: at any point x that is not a fixed point of f, the direction of

f(x)-x

is grossly preserved in some neighborhood of x, in the sense that for any two points y, z in this neighborhood, its inner product is non-negative, i.e.:

(f(y)-y)(f(z)-z)\geq0

. Then f has a fixed point in X.

The theorem is originally stated for polytopes, but Philippe Bich extends it to convex compact sets.[7] Note that every continuous function is LGDP, but an LGDP function may be discontinuous. An LGDP function may even be neither upper nor lower semi-continuous. Moreover, there is a constructive algorithm for approximating this fixed point.

Applications

Discrete fixed-point theorems have been used to prove the existence of a Nash equilibrium in a discrete game, and the existence of a Walrasian equilibrium in a discrete market.[8]

Notes and References

  1. Iimura. Takuya. 2003-09-01. A discrete fixed point theorem and its applications. Journal of Mathematical Economics. en. 39. 7. 725–742. 10.1016/S0304-4068(03)00007-7. 0304-4068.
  2. Iimura. Takuya. Murota. Kazuo. Tamura. Akihisa. 2005-12-01. Discrete fixed point theorem reconsidered. Journal of Mathematical Economics. en. 41. 8. 1030–1036. 10.1016/j.jmateco.2005.03.001. 0304-4068.
  3. Book: Chen. Xi. Deng. Xiaotie. 2006. Chen. Danny Z.. Lee. D. T.. A Simplicial Approach for Discrete Fixed Point Theorems. Computing and Combinatorics. Lecture Notes in Computer Science. 4112. en. Berlin, Heidelberg. Springer. 3–12. 10.1007/11809678_3. 978-3-540-36926-4.
  4. Yang. Zaifu. 2009-12-01. 2004 (FBA working paper no. 210, Yokohama National University). Discrete fixed point analysis and its applications. Journal of Fixed Point Theory and Applications. en. 6. 2. 351–371. 10.1007/s11784-009-0130-9. 122640338. 1661-7746.
  5. Yang. Zaifu. 2008-11-01. On the Solutions of Discrete Nonlinear Complementarity and Related Problems. Mathematics of Operations Research. 33. 4. 976–990. 10.1287/moor.1080.0343. 0364-765X.
  6. Jean-Jacques Herings. P.. van der Laan. Gerard. Talman. Dolf. Yang. Zaifu. 2008-01-01. A fixed point theorem for discontinuous functions. Operations Research Letters. en. 36. 1. 89–93. 10.1016/j.orl.2007.03.008. 14117444 . 0167-6377. 10419/86189. free.
  7. Bich . Philippe . 2006 . Some fixed point theorems for discontinuous mappings . Cahiers de la Maison des Sciences Économiques . en.
  8. Iimura. Takuya. Yang. Zaifu. 2009-12-01. A study on the demand and response correspondences in the presence of indivisibilities. Journal of Fixed Point Theory and Applications. en. 6. 2. 333–349. 10.1007/s11784-009-0131-8. 121519442. 1661-7746.