Discrete fixed-point theorem explained
In discrete mathematics, a discrete fixed-point is a fixed-point for functions defined on finite sets, typically subsets of the integer grid
.
Discrete fixed-point theorems were developed by Iimura,[1] Murota and Tamura,[2] Chen and Deng[3] and others. Yang[4] provides a survey.
Basic concepts
Continuous fixed-point theorems often require a continuous function. Since continuity is not meaningful for functions on discrete sets, it is replaced by conditions such as a direction-preserving function. Such conditions imply that the function does not change too drastically when moving between neighboring points of the integer grid. There are various direction-preservation conditions, depending on whether neighboring points are considered points of a hypercube (HGDP), of a simplex (SGDP) etc. See the page on direction-preserving function for definitions.
Continuous fixed-point theorems often require a convex set. The analogue of this property for discrete sets is an integrally-convex set.
A fixed point of a discrete function f is defined exactly as for continuous functions: it is a point x for which f(x)=x.
For functions on discrete sets
We focus on functions
, where the domain X is a nonempty subset of the Euclidean space
. ch(
X) denotes the
convex hull of
X.
Iimura-Murota-Tamura theorem: If X is a finite integrally-convex subset of
, and
is a
hypercubic direction-preserving (HDP) function, then
f has a fixed-point.
Chen-Deng theorem: If X is a finite subset of
, and
is
simplicially direction-preserving (SDP), then
f has a fixed-point.
Yang's theorems:
,
is
simplicially gross direction preserving (SGDP), and for all
x in
X there exists some
g(
x)>0 such that
, then
f has a zero point.
- [3.7] If X is a finite hypercubic subset of
, with minimum point
a and maximum point
b,
is SGDP, and for any
x in
X:
fi(x1,\ldots,xi-1,ai,xi+1,\ldots,xn)\leq0
and
fi(x1,\ldots,xi-1,bi,xi+1,\ldots,xn)\geq0
, then
f has a zero point. This is a discrete analogue of the
Poincaré–Miranda theorem. It is a consequence of the previous theorem.
, and
is such that
is
SGDP, then
f has a fixed-point.
[5] This is a discrete analogue of the
Brouwer fixed-point theorem.
,
is bounded and
is SGDP, then
f has a fixed-point (this follows easily from the previous theorem by taking
X to be a subset of
that bounds
f).
,
a
point-to-set mapping, and for all
x in
X:
, and there is a function
f such that
and
is SGDP, then there is a point
y in
X such that
. This is a discrete analogue of the
Kakutani fixed-point theorem, and the function
f is an analogue of a continuous
selection function.
, and it is also
symmetric in the sense that
x is in
X iff -
x is in
X. If
is SGDP w.r.t. a
weakly-symmetric triangulation of ch(
X) (in the sense that if
s is a simplex on the boundary of the triangulation iff -
s is), and
for every pair of simplicially-connected points
x,
y in the boundary of ch(
X), then
f has a zero point.
- See the survey for more theorems.
For discontinuous functions on continuous sets
Discrete fixed-point theorems are closely related to fixed-point theorems on discontinuous functions. These, too, use the direction-preservation condition instead of continuity.
Herings-Laan-Talman-Yang fixed-point theorem:[6]
Let X be a non-empty convex compact subset of
. Let
f:
X →
X be a
locally gross direction preserving (LGDP) function: at any point
x that is not a fixed point of
f, the direction of
is grossly preserved in some
neighborhood of
x, in the sense that for any two points
y,
z in this neighborhood, its inner product is non-negative, i.e.:
. Then
f has a fixed point in
X.
The theorem is originally stated for polytopes, but Philippe Bich extends it to convex compact sets.[7] Note that every continuous function is LGDP, but an LGDP function may be discontinuous. An LGDP function may even be neither upper nor lower semi-continuous. Moreover, there is a constructive algorithm for approximating this fixed point.
Applications
Discrete fixed-point theorems have been used to prove the existence of a Nash equilibrium in a discrete game, and the existence of a Walrasian equilibrium in a discrete market.[8]
Notes and References
- Iimura. Takuya. 2003-09-01. A discrete fixed point theorem and its applications. Journal of Mathematical Economics. en. 39. 7. 725–742. 10.1016/S0304-4068(03)00007-7. 0304-4068.
- Iimura. Takuya. Murota. Kazuo. Tamura. Akihisa. 2005-12-01. Discrete fixed point theorem reconsidered. Journal of Mathematical Economics. en. 41. 8. 1030–1036. 10.1016/j.jmateco.2005.03.001. 0304-4068.
- Book: Chen. Xi. Deng. Xiaotie. 2006. Chen. Danny Z.. Lee. D. T.. A Simplicial Approach for Discrete Fixed Point Theorems. Computing and Combinatorics. Lecture Notes in Computer Science. 4112. en. Berlin, Heidelberg. Springer. 3–12. 10.1007/11809678_3. 978-3-540-36926-4.
- Yang. Zaifu. 2009-12-01. 2004 (FBA working paper no. 210, Yokohama National University). Discrete fixed point analysis and its applications. Journal of Fixed Point Theory and Applications. en. 6. 2. 351–371. 10.1007/s11784-009-0130-9. 122640338. 1661-7746.
- Yang. Zaifu. 2008-11-01. On the Solutions of Discrete Nonlinear Complementarity and Related Problems. Mathematics of Operations Research. 33. 4. 976–990. 10.1287/moor.1080.0343. 0364-765X.
- Jean-Jacques Herings. P.. van der Laan. Gerard. Talman. Dolf. Yang. Zaifu. 2008-01-01. A fixed point theorem for discontinuous functions. Operations Research Letters. en. 36. 1. 89–93. 10.1016/j.orl.2007.03.008. 14117444 . 0167-6377. 10419/86189. free.
- Bich . Philippe . 2006 . Some fixed point theorems for discontinuous mappings . Cahiers de la Maison des Sciences Économiques . en.
- Iimura. Takuya. Yang. Zaifu. 2009-12-01. A study on the demand and response correspondences in the presence of indivisibilities. Journal of Fixed Point Theory and Applications. en. 6. 2. 333–349. 10.1007/s11784-009-0131-8. 121519442. 1661-7746.