Consumption function explained

In economics, the consumption function describes a relationship between consumption and disposable income.[1] [2] The concept is believed to have been introduced into macroeconomics by John Maynard Keynes in 1936, who used it to develop the notion of a government spending multiplier.[3]

Details

Its simplest form is the linear consumption function used frequently in simple Keynesian models:[4]

C=a+bYd

where

a

is the autonomous consumption that is independent of disposable income; in other words, consumption when disposable income is zero. The term

bYd

is the induced consumption that is influenced by the economy's income level

Yd

. The parameter

b

is known as the marginal propensity to consume, i.e. the increase in consumption due to an incremental increase in disposable income, since

\partialC/\partialYd=b

. Geometrically,

b

is the slope of the consumption function.

Keynes proposed this model to fit three stylized facts:[5]

b\in(0,1)

.
C
Yd
decreasing with

Yd

.

By basing his model in how typical households decide how much to save and spend, Keynes was informally using a microfoundation approach to the macroeconomics of saving.[7]

Keynes also took note of the tendency for the marginal propensity to consume to decrease as income increases, i.e.

\partial2C/\partial

2
Y
d

<0

.[8] If this assumption is to be used, it would result in a nonlinear consumption function with a diminishing slope. Further theories on the shape of the consumption function include James Duesenberry's (1949) relative consumption expenditure,[9] Franco Modigliani and Richard Brumberg's (1954) life-cycle hypothesis, and Milton Friedman's (1957) permanent income hypothesis.[10]

Some new theoretical works following Duesenberry's and based in behavioral economics suggest that a number of behavioural principles can be taken as microeconomic foundations for a behaviorally-based aggregate consumption function.[11]

See also

Further reading

External links

Notes and References

  1. Algebraically, this means

    C=f(Yd)

    where

    f\colonR+\toR+

    is a function that maps levels of disposable income

    Yd

    —income after government intervention, such as taxes or transfer payments—into levels of consumption

    C

    .
  2. Book: Lindauer, John . John Lindauer . Macroeconomics . New York . John Wiley & Sons . Third . 1976 . 0-471-53572-9 . 40–43 .
  3. Book: Hall . Robert E. . Robert Hall (economist) . Taylor . John B. . John B. Taylor . Consumption and Income . 63–67 . Macroeconomics: Theory, Performance, and Policy . New York . W. W. Norton . 1986 . 0-393-95398-X .
  4. Book: Colander, David . David Colander . Macroeconomics: Theory and Policy . Glenview . Scott, Foresman and Co. . 1986 . 0-673-16648-1 . 94–97 . registration .
  5. Book: Mankiw, N. Gregory . Macroeconomics . 2022 . 978-1-319-26390-4 . 11 . New York . 20-1 What Determines Consumer Spending? . 1289514240.
  6. Book: Keynes, John M. . . Harcourt Brace Jovanovich . 1936 . New York . Section 3.8.2 . There are not many people who will alter their way of living because the rate of interest has fallen from 5 to 4 per cent, if their aggregate income is the same as before... the short-period influence of the rate of interest on individual spending out of a given income is secondary and relatively unimportant, except, perhaps, where unusually large changes are in question..
  7. Solow . Robert M. . 2004 . Introduction: The Tobin Approach to Monetary Economics . Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking . 36 . 4 . 657–663 . 10.1353/mcb.2004.0067 . 154008365 . 1538-4616 . ... recall Keynes’s argument that the marginal propensity to consume should be between zero and one, or his discussion about whether the marginal efficiency of investment should be sensitive to current output or should depend primarily on “the state of long-term expectations.” Those are microfoundations..
  8. Book: Keynes, John M.. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. Harcourt Brace Jovanovich. 1936. New York. The marginal propensity to consume is not constant for all levels of employment, and it is probable that there will be, as a rule, a tendency for it to diminish as employment increases; when real income increases, that is to say, the community will wish to consume a gradually diminishing proportion of it..
  9. Book: Duesenberry, J. S. . 1949 . Income, Saving and the Theory of Consumer Behavior .
  10. Book: Friedman, M. . 1957 . A Theory of the Consumption Function .
  11. 10.1016/j.joep.2010.09.004. Behavioral foundations for the Keynesian consumption function. Journal of Economic Psychology. 31. 6. 1035. 2010. d’Orlando . F. . Sanfilippo . E. .