Workers' self-management explained

Workers' self-management, also referred to as labor management and organizational self-management, is a form of organizational management based on self-directed work processes on the part of an organization's workforce. Self-management is a defining characteristic of socialism, with proposals for self-management having appeared many times throughout the history of the socialist movement, advocated variously by democratic, libertarian and market socialists as well as anarchists and communists.[1]

There are many variations of self-management. In some variants, all the worker-members manage the enterprise directly through assemblies while in other forms workers exercise management functions indirectly through the election of specialist managers. Self-management may include worker supervision and oversight of an organization by elected bodies, the election of specialized managers, or self-directed management without any specialized managers as such.[2] The goals of self-management are to improve performance by granting workers greater autonomy in their day-to-day operations, boosting morale, reducing alienation and eliminating exploitation when paired with employee ownership.[3]

An enterprise that is self-managed is referred to as a labour-managed firm. Self-management refers to control rights within a productive organization, being distinct from the questions of ownership and what economic system the organization operates under.[4] Self-management of an organization may coincide with employee ownership of that organization, but self-management can also exist in the context of organizations under public ownership and to a limited extent within private companies in the form of co-determination and worker representation on the board of directors.

Economic theory

An economic system consisting of self-managed enterprises is sometimes referred to as a participatory economy, self-managed economy, or cooperative economy. This economic model is a major version of market socialism and decentralized planned economy, stemming from the notion that people should be able to participate in making the decisions that affect their well-being. The major proponents of self-managed market socialism in the 20th century include the economists Benjamin N. Ward, Jaroslav Vanek and Branko Horvat.[5] Horvat says that participation is not simply more desirable, but also more economically viable than traditional hierarchical and authoritarian management as demonstrated by econometric measurements which indicate an increase in efficiency with greater participation in decision-making. Writing from the perspective of socialist Yugoslavia in the early 1980s, Horvat suggested that the larger world was moving toward a self-governing socialistic mode of organization as well.[6]

Labor managed firm

The theory of the labor managed firm explains the behavior, performance and nature of self-managed organizational forms. Although self-managed (or labor-managed) firms can coincide with worker ownership (employee ownership), the two are distinct concepts and one need not imply the other.

Neoclassical economics

According to traditional neoclassical economic theory, in a competitive market economy ownership of capital assets by labor (the workforce of a given firm) should have no significant impact on firm performance.[7]

Much of the research on labor-managed firms in the neoclassical tradition revolved around the question of the presumed maximand (objective function) of such firms (i.e. the answer to the question "what do labor-managed firms maximize?", e.g. income per worker or profits) and its implications.[8] The first model of a labor-managed firm in this tradition has been suggested by American economist Benjamin Ward in 1958 who was interested in the analysis of Yugoslav firms.[9] According to Ward, the labor-managed firm strives to maximize income per worker as contrasted with the traditional capitalist firms' objective function of maximizing profit for external owners. Based on this assumption, Ward presented an analysis that was critical of labor-managed firms. In particular, he argued that a supply curve of a labor-managed firm has a negative slope: an increase in the market price of the product produced by a labor-managed firm will not make it increase production and hire new members. It followed that an economy consisting of labor-managed firms would have a tendency to underutilize labor and tend toward higher rates of unemployment. Ward's model was developed further by Evsey Domar and generalized by Jaroslav Vaněk.[10]

These purely theoretical analyses were criticized by Yugoslav economist Branko Horvat in 1971 who argued for empirical analysis of actually existing labor-managed Yugoslav firms and practices utilized by their members. In particular, he noted that workers fix wages at the beginning of a year and then adjust them based on the earnings of the enterprise. He noted that this behavioral rule, if made a part of the theoretical model, implies that the market behavior of a labor-managed firm is, contrary to theses by Ward and his followers, much more similar to the hypothetical behavior of a "traditional", profit-maximizing firm.[11]

Building on a larger body of empirical studies, contemporary Canadian economist Gregory Dow has carried out extensive theoretical research on labor-managed firms from the neoclassical perspective, focussing on explaining the rarity of labor-managed firms relative to capital-managed ones.[12]

Classical economics

In the 19th century, the idea of a self-managed economy was first fully articulated by the anarchist philosopher and economist Pierre-Joseph Proudhon.[13] This economic model was called mutualism to highlight the mutual relationship among individuals in this system and involved cooperatives operating in a free-market economy.

The classical liberal philosopher and economist John Stuart Mill believed that worker-run and owned cooperatives would eventually displace traditional capitalist (capital-managed) firms in the competitive market economy due to their superior efficiency and stronger incentive structure. While both Mill and Karl Marx thought that democratic worker management would be more efficient in the long run compared with hierarchical management, Marx was not hopeful about the prospects of labor-managed and owned firms as a means to displace traditional capitalist firms in the market economy.[14] Despite their advantages in efficiency, in Western market economies the labor-managed firm is comparatively rare.[15]

Karl Marx championed the idea of a free association of producers as a characteristic of communist society, where self-management processes replaced the traditional notion of the centralized state. This concept is related to the Marxist idea of transcending alienation.[16]

Soviet-type economic planning

The Soviet-type economic model as practiced in the former USSR and Eastern Bloc (Russian: самоуправление; [17]) was introduced in the state-owned enterprises in the 1980s.[18] It is criticized by socialists for its lack of widespread self-management and management input on the part of workers in enterprises.[19]

Management science

In his book , Daniel H. Pink argues on the basis of empirical evidence that self-management/self-directed processes, mastery, worker autonomy and purpose (defined as intrinsic rewards) are much more effective incentives than monetary gain (extrinsic rewards). According to Pink, for the vast majority of work in the 21st century self-management and related intrinsic incentives are far more crucial than outdated notions of hierarchical management and an overreliance on monetary compensation as reward.

More recent research suggests that incentives and bonuses can have positive effects on performance and autonomous motivation.[20] According to this research, the key is aligning bonuses and incentives to reinforce, rather than hamper, a sense of autonomy, competence and relatedness (the three needs that self determination theory identifies for autonomous motivation).

Political movements

Europe

Guild socialism is a political movement advocating workers' control of industry through the medium of trade-related guilds "in an implied contractual relationship with the public".[21] It originated in the United Kingdom and was at its most influential in the first quarter of the 20th century. It was strongly associated with G. D. H. Cole and influenced by the ideas of William Morris. One significant experiment with workers' self-management took place during the Spanish Revolution (1936–1939).[22] In his book Anarcho-Syndicalism (1938), Rudolf Rocker stated:

But by taking the land and the industrial plants under their own management they have taken the first and most important step on the road to Socialism. Above all, they (the Workers' and peasants self-management) have proved that the workers, even without the capitalists, are able to carry on production and to do it better than a lot of profit-hungry entrepreneurs.[23]
After May 1968 in France, LIP factory, a clockwork factory based in Besançon, became self-managed starting in 1973 after the management's decision to liquidate it. The LIP experience was an emblematic social conflict of post-1968 in France. CFDT (the CCT as it was referred to in Northern Spain), trade-unionist Charles Piaget led the strike in which workers claimed the means of production. The Unified Socialist Party (PSU) which included former Radical Pierre Mendès-France was in favour of autogestión or self-management.[24]

In the Basque Country of Spain, the Mondragon Cooperative Corporation represents perhaps the longest lasting and most successful example of workers' self-management in the world. It has been touted by a diverse group of people such as the Marxian economist Richard D. Wolff and the research book Capital and the Debt Trap by Claudia Sanchez Bajo and Bruno Roelants[25] as an example of how the economy can be organized on an alternative to the capitalist mode of production.[26]

Following the 2007–2008 financial crisis, a number of factories were occupied and became self-managed in Greece,[27] France,[28] Italy,[29] Germany[30] and Turkey.[31]

In Greece, solidarity-based distribution is partially the result of austerity policies' privatization of public services, which exacerbates on-the-ground solidarity activities. These have mostly emerged as a consequence of ambitious politicized thinking and mobilization, as well as a practical formulation that ensures degrees of living by transforming informal solidarity networks into remunerative distribution cooperatives. This dialectic, echoes the idea of formally managing the crisis, which reproduces itself not in spite of, but because of, official policy initiatives to combat it.[32] Workers' collectives and cooperatives, Self-Help Groups, Local Exchange Trade Systems (LETS), Freecycle networks and Timebanks, and the first worker-occupied factory are examples of non-capitalist social experiments and innovations that have emerged in Greece since 2012.[33]

Yugoslavia

At the height of the Cold War, Yugoslavia, as a consequence of the Tito-Stalin split, pursued and advocated for, what was officially called, socialist self-management in distinction from the Eastern Bloc countries, all of which practiced central planning and centralized management of their economies. It replaced central planning with planning basic proportions that was supposed to stop "the chaos of social production and distribution that is innate to capitalism".[34] It was organized according to the theories of Josip Broz Tito and more directly Edvard Kardelj. Yugoslav economist Branko Horvat also made a significant contribution to the theory of workers' self-management (radničko samoupravljanje) as practiced in Yugoslavia. Due to Yugoslavia's neutrality and its leading role in the Non-Aligned Movement, Yugoslav companies exported to both Western and Eastern markets. Yugoslav companies carried out construction of numerous major infrastructural and industrial projects in Africa, Europe and Asia.[35] [36]

In 1950, the Law on self-management introduced worker's councils. The "beginning of the end of bureaucracy" was declared along the pretenses of the Marxist concept of withering away of the state under the "Factories to the workers'!" parole. According to Boris Kanzleiter, the inspiration for workers' councils came from the People's councils – the revolutionary governing bodies of the People's Liberation Army and the Paris Commune.[37] The 1953 Yugoslav Constitutional Law, introduced self-management in the constitutional matter and transformed state property into social property. The 1963 Yugoslav Constitution, also called the Charter of Self-management, defined self-management and social property as supreme values and it defined Yugoslavia as a "socialist self-managed democratic community".[38]

The Law of Associated Labor of 1976 represented the last stage of the development of Yugoslav self-management. On the grounds of the 1974 Yugoslav constitution, it created a completely autonomous system grounded in direct sovereignty of the worker and citizen. It foresaw the formation of Basic Organizations of Associated Labor (BOAL) as the basic economic units that every worker had to be a part of based on the precise role played by that worker in the production process. It associated with other BOALs to form an Organization of Associated Labour (OAL) that could, with other OALs form Complex Organizations of Associated Labor. The assembly that consisted of all the workers' of a BOAL elected a delegate, which was bound with an imperative mandate, into the workers' council of the OAL that decided on all matters: from electing the director, to decisions on salaries, investments, association, development and specific production goals. Another feature of Yugoslav self-management were Self-management agreements and Social compacts, these replaced classical contracts.[39] The goal of OALs was not for-profit but a social goal – it was supposed to facilitate education, healthcare, employment and resolving the housing issue.[40]

Macro-economic reforms and structural adjustment programs that were imposed by the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World Bank brought an end to workers' self-management in Yugoslavia.[41] [42]

Empresas recuperadas movement

English-language discussions of this phenomenon may employ several different translations of the original Spanish expression other than recovered factory. For example, worker-recuperated enterprise, recuperated/recovered factory/business/company, worker-recovered factory/business, worker-recuperated/recovered company, worker-reclaimed factory, and worker-run factory have been noted.[43] The phenomenon is also known as autogestión.[43]

Argentina's empresas recuperadas movement emerged in response to the run up and aftershocks of Argentina's 2001 economic crisis. Empresas recuperadas means "reclaimed/recovered/recuperated enterprises/factories/companies". The Spanish verb recuperar means not only "to get back", "to take back" or "to reclaim", but also "to put back into good condition".[44]

The movement emerged as a response to the years of crisis leading up to and including Argentina's 2001 economic crisis.[45] By 2001–2002, around 200 Argentine companies were recuperated by their workers and turned into worker co-operatives. Prominent examples include the Brukman factory, the Hotel Bauen and FaSinPat (formerly known as Zanon). As of 2020, around 16,000 Argentine workers run close to 400 recuperated factories.[44]

The phenomenon of empresas recuperadas ("recovered enterprises") is not new in Argentina. Rather, such social movements were completely dismantled during the so-called Dirty War in the 1970s. Thus, during Héctor Cámpora's first months of government (May–July 1973), a rather moderate and left-wing Peronist, approximately 600 social conflicts, strikes and factory occupations had taken place.[46]

The proliferation of these "recuperations" has led to the formation of a recuperated factory movement which has ties to a diverse political network including socialists, Peronists, anarchists and communists. Organizationally, this includes two major federations of recovered factories, the larger Movimiento Nacional de Empresas Recuperadas (National Movement of Recuperated Businesses, or MNER) on the left and the smaller National Movement of Recuperated Factories (MNFR)[47] on the right.[48]

The movement led in 2011 to a new bankruptcy law that facilitates take over by the workers.[49] The legislation was signed into law by President Cristina Kirchner on June 29, 2011.[50]

See also

Self-managed organizations

References

Further reading

Documentary-film

External links

Notes and References

  1. Book: Steele, David . From Marx to Mises: Post-Capitalist Society and the Challenge of Economic Calculation . Open Court Publishing Company . 1992. 978-0875484495. 323. The proposal that all the workers in a workplace should be in charge of the management of that workplace has appeared in various forms throughout the history of socialism. [...] [A]mong the labels attached to this form of organization are 'self-management', 'labor management', 'workers' control', 'workplace democracy', 'industrial democracy' and 'producers' cooperatives'..
  2. Book: Steele, David . From Marx to Mises: Post-Capitalist Society and the Challenge of Economic Calculation . Open Court Publishing Company . 1992. 978-0875484495. 323. The self-management idea has many variants. All the workers may manage together directly, by means of an assembly, or indirectly by electing a supervisory board. They may manage in co-operation with a group of specialized managers or they may do without them..
  3. Book: O'Hara, Phillip . Encyclopedia of Political Economy, Volume 2 . Routledge. 2003. 978-0-415-24187-8. 9. In eliminating the domination of capital over labour, firms run by workers eliminate capitalist exploitation and reduce alienation..
  4. Book: Prychito, David L. . Markets, Planning, and Democracy: Essays After the Collapse of Communism . Edward Elgar Pub. 2002. 978-1840645194. 71. The labor-managed firm is a productive organization whose ultimate decision making rights rest in the workers of the firm...In this sense workers' self-management – as a basic principle – is about establishing control rights within a productive organization, while it leaves open the issue of de jure ownership (that is, who enjoys legal title to the physical and financial assets of the firm) and the type of economic system in which the firm is operating..
  5. Book: Gregory and Stuart, Paul and Robert . Comparing Economic Systems in the Twenty-First Century . 7th . George Hoffman. 2004 . 978-0-618-26181-9. 145–146.
  6. Book: Horvat, Branko . The Political Economy of Socialism: A Marxist Social Theory . M.E Sharpe Inc . 1983 . 978-0873322560 . 173 . Participation is not only more desirable, it is also economically more viable than traditional authoritarian management. Econometric measurements indicate that efficiency increases with participation...There is little doubt that the world is moving toward a socialist, self-governing society at an accelerated pace. .
  7. Paul Samuelson, Wages and Interest: A Modern Dissection of Marxian Economic Models, 47 Am.Econ.Rev. 884, 894 (1957): "In a perfectly competitive market it really doesn't matter who hires whom: so have labor hire 'capital'...")
  8. Book: Nuti, Mario . 1996 . Pagano . Ugo . Rowthorn . RObert . Democracy and Efficiency in the Economic Enterprise. London: Routledge . 184–206 . Efficiency, equality and enterprise democracy. . A massive body of literature from Ward's seminal model of the "Illyria" firm (1958) and its generalization by Vanek (1970) to date, probably larger than for any other single economic issue, has accumulated on the economic implications of the presumed maximand of self-managed enterprises..
  9. Horvat. Branko. 1971 . Yugoslav Economic Policy in the Post-War Period: Problems, Ideas, Institutional Developments. The American Economic Review. 61. 3. Theoretical analysis of the behavior of the Yugoslav firm has only begun. Oddly or understandably enough, the pioneering work was done by a foreigner, B. Ward of the University of California at Berkeley..
  10. Horvat. Branko. 1971. Yugoslav Economic Policy in the Post-War Period: Problems, Ideas, Institutional Developments. The American Economic Review. 61. 3. In a similar analysis eight years later, Domar showed that by generalizing the production function to include several products and several factors and by introducing the demand curve for labor the results are changed and begin to resemble the traditional conclusions about the behavior of the firm (Domar, 1966)..
  11. Horvat. Branko. 1971. Yugoslav Economic Policy in the Post-War Period: Problems, Ideas, Institutional Developments . The American Economic Review. 61. 3. Instead of postulating what should be rational, the present author observes the actual practice of Yugoslav enterprises which fix wages in advance for the current year, and at least once a year make corrections (positive or negative) depending on the income earned. If this behavioral rule is used in the analysis, the results are again the same as in the traditional theory of the firm..
  12. Web site: Greg Dow – Research. 2022-04-10. 2019-01-20. https://web.archive.org/web/20190120115801/http://www.sfu.ca/~gdow/. live.
  13. Book: Proudhon, Pierre-Joseph. 'Oeuvres Complètes', volume 17. 1866–1876. Lacroix. Paris. 188–189.
  14. Where Did Mill Go Wrong?: Why the Capital-Managed Firm Rather than the Labor–Managed Enterprise Is the Predominant Organizational Form in Market Economies, by Schwartz, Justin. 2011. Ohio State Law Journal, vol. 73, no. 2, 2012: "Why, then, is the predominant form of industrial organization in market societies the traditional capital-owned and managed firm (the capitalist firm) rather than the labor-managed enterprise owned and managed by the workers (the cooperative)? This is exactly the opposite of the result predicted by John Stuart Mill over 150 years ago. He thought that such worker-run cooperative associations would eventually crowd capitalist firms out of the market because of their superior efficiency and other advantages for workers."
  15. Where Did Mill Go Wrong?: Why the Capital-Managed Firm Rather than the Labor-Managed Enterprise Is the Predominant Organizational Form in Market Economies, by Schwartz, Justin. 2011. Ohio State Law Journal, vol. 73, no. 2, 2012: "Mill was mistaken, and Marx correct, at least about the tendency for labor-managed firms to displace capital-managed firms in the ordinary operation of the market."
  16. Book: O'Hara, Phillip . Encyclopedia of Political Economy, Volume 2 . Routledge. 2003. 978-0-415-24187-8. 836. it influenced Marx to champion the ideas of a "free association of producers" and of self-management replacing the centralized state..
  17. Book: Amann . Ronald . Cooper . Julian . 1986 . Technical Progress and Soviet Economic Development . Self-management (samoupravlenie) . Oxford . Basil Blackwell . 156 . 0-631-14572-9.
  18. Book: Robinson, Neil . 1995 . Ideology and the Collapse of the Soviet System: A Critical History of Soviet Ideological Discourse . Brookfield, Vermont . Edward Elgar Publishing Co. . 101 . 1-85898-167-0.
  19. Book: Ellman, Michael . Socialist Planning . Cambridge University Press . 1989 . 978-0-521-35866-8 . 312 . In general, it seems reasonable to say that the state socialist countries have made no progress whatsoever towards organizing the labour process so as to end the division between the scientist and the process workers. This is scarcely surprising, both in view of the Bolshevik attitude toward Taylorism and in view of Marx's own thesis that a society in which the labour process has been transformed would be one in which technical progress had eliminated dreary, repetitive, work. Such a state of affairs has not yet been reached in even the most advanced countries..
  20. Gerhart . Barry . Fang . Meiyu . Pay, Intrinsic Motivation, Extrinsic Motivation, Performance, and Creativity in the Workplace: Revisiting Long-Held Beliefs . Annual Review of Organizational Psychology and Organizational Behavior . 10 April 2015 . 2 . 1 . 489–521 . 10.1146/annurev-orgpsych-032414-111418 . 6 November 2019 . 19 April 2022 . https://web.archive.org/web/20220419204326/https://www.academia.edu/37709060 . live . free .
  21. Web site: "Guild Socialism". Encyclopædia Britannica. Encyclopædia Britannica Online. Encyclopædia Britannica Inc.,2012 . 2013-10-08 . 2013-10-12 . https://web.archive.org/web/20131012094417/http://www.britannica.com/EBchecked/topic/248652/Guild-Socialism . live .
  22. Book: The Anarchist Collectives: Workers' Self-Management in the Spanish Revolution. 1974. Dolgoff, S.. 978-0-914156-03-1. The Anarchist Collectives. Free Life Editions .
  23. [Rudolf Rocker|Rocker, Rudolf]
  24. http://www.monde-diplomatique.fr/carnet/2007-03-20-LIP LIP, l'imagination au pouvoir
  25. Web site: Sanchez Bajo. Claudia. Roelants. Bruno. Capital and the Debt Trap: learning from cooperatives in the global crisis. Palgrave MacMillan. 12 February 2016. 16 February 2016. https://web.archive.org/web/20160216045351/http://www.capital-and-the-debt-trap.com/. live.
  26. [Richard D. Wolff]
  27. Web site: Vio.Me: workers' control in the Greek crisis. www.workerscontrol.net. 2020-05-07. 2020-06-09. https://web.archive.org/web/20200609060100/https://www.workerscontrol.net/authors/viome-workers-control-greek-crisis. live.
  28. Web site: Take back the factory: worker control in the current crisis. www.workerscontrol.net. 2020-05-07. 2020-06-23. https://web.archive.org/web/20200623065210/http://www.workerscontrol.net/authors/take-back-factory-worker-control-current-crisis. live.
  29. Web site: Occupy, Resist, Produce – Officine Zero. www.workerscontrol.net. 2020-05-07. 2020-08-10. https://web.archive.org/web/20200810025445/https://www.workerscontrol.net/authors/occupy-resist-produce-%E2%80%93-officine-zero. live.
  30. Web site: Strike Bike: an occupied factory in Germany. www.workerscontrol.net. 2020-05-07. 2020-09-25. https://web.archive.org/web/20200925215750/http://www.workerscontrol.net/geographical/strike-bike-occupied-factory-germany. live.
  31. Web site: Kazova workers claim historic victory in Turkey. www.workerscontrol.net. 2020-05-07. 2021-02-11. https://web.archive.org/web/20210211081357/http://www.workerscontrol.net/authors/kazova-workers-claim-historic-victory-turkey. live.
  32. Rakopoulos . Theodoros . June 2014 . The criris seem from below, within, and against: From solidarity economy to food distribution cooperatives in Greece . Dialectical Anthropology . 38 . 2 . 189–207 . 10.1007/s10624-014-9342-5 . 2263/41201 . 143873220 . 2022-04-13 . 2022-04-13 . https://web.archive.org/web/20220413133432/https://www.researchgate.net/publication/272011441_The_crisis_seen_from_below_within_and_against_From_solidarity_economy_to_food_distribution_cooperatives_in_Greece . live . free .
  33. Kokkinidis . George . November 2015 . Spaces of possibilities: workers'self-management in Greece . Organization . 22 . 6 . 847–871 . 10.1177/1350508414521098 . 53488748 . 2022-04-13 . 2022-04-13 . https://web.archive.org/web/20220413133432/https://journals.sagepub.com/doi/abs/10.1177/1350508414521098 . live . 2381/31746 . free .
  34. Web site: znaci.net . 2022-04-11 . znaci.net . 2020-01-09 . https://web.archive.org/web/20200109024709/http://www.znaci.net/00001/95_10.pdf . live .
  35. Liotta . P.H. . 2001-12-31 . Paradigm Lost :Yugoslav Self-Management and the Economics of Disaster . Balkanologie. Revue d'Études Pluridisciplinaires . V. 1–2 . 10.4000/balkanologie.681 . 18 August 2010 . free . 2010-08-01 . https://web.archive.org/web/20100801081840/http://balkanologie.revues.org/index681.html . live .
  36. Web site: December 1990 . Yugoslavia: Introduction of Socialist Self-Management . 18 August 2010 . Country Data . 9 December 2004 . https://web.archive.org/web/20041209214334/http://www.country-data.com/cgi-bin/query/r-14787.html . live .
  37. Book: Tomašević, Tomislav . Commons in Southeast Europe: Case of Croatia, Bosnia & Herzegovina and Macedonia . Institute for Political Ecology . 2018 . 978-953-58938-3-7 . Zagreb . 61 . sh.
  38. Book: Constitution of Socialist Federal Republic of Yugoslavia . 2022-04-11 . 2022-04-11 . https://web.archive.org/web/20220411150109/https://en.wikisource.org/wiki/Constitution_of_Yugoslavia_(1974) . live .
  39. Web site: Yugoslavia – The Economic Management Mechanism . 2022-04-11 . www.country-data.com . 2021-10-09 . https://web.archive.org/web/20211009043710/http://www.country-data.com/cgi-bin/query/r-14846.html . live .
  40. Web site: Zakon o udruženom radu (1976) – Викизворник, слободна библиотека . 2022-04-11 . sr.wikisource.org . sr . 2020-09-20 . https://web.archive.org/web/20200920025332/https://sr.wikisource.org/wiki/Zakon_o_udru%C5%BEenom_radu_(1976) . live .
  41. Book: Lebowitz, Michael . Lecciones de la autogestión yugoslava . Encuentro Mundial de Solidaridad con la Revolución Bolivariana . 2004 . Caracas . 9 . es.
  42. Book: Allen, Bob . Why Kosovo? Anatomy of a Needless War . Canadian Center for Policy Alternatives. 1999 . 0-88627-963-1 . National Office, BC Office . 11–13 . en.
  43. Vieta, Marcelo, 2020, Workers' Self-Management in Argentina: Contesting Neo-Liberalism by Occupying Companies, Creating Cooperatives, and Recuperating Autogestión, Brill, Leiden.
  44. Vieta, Marcelo, 2020, Workers' Self-Management in Argentina: Contesting Neo-Liberalism by Occupying Companies, Creating Cooperatives, and Recuperating Autogestión, Brill, Leiden, pp. 517–519.
  45. Guido Galafassi, Paula Lenguita, Robinson Salazar Perez (2004) Nuevas Practicas Politicas Insumisas En Argentina pp. 222, 238.
  46. Hugo Moreno, Le désastre argentin. Péronisme, politique et violence sociale (1930–2001), Editions Syllepses, Paris, 2005, p. 109 .
  47. http://www.fabricasrecuperadas.org.ar/ Movimiento Nacional de Fabricas Recuperadas
  48. Marie Trigona, Recuperated Enterprises in Argentina – Reversing the Logic of Capitalism, Znet, March 27, 2006.
  49. Pagina12: Nueva Ley de Quiebras (April 2011), Fábricas recuperadas y también legales (June 2nd 2011)
  50. http://www.pagina12.com.ar/diario/ultimas/20-171094-2011-06-29.html CFK promulgó la reforma de la Ley de Quiebras