Tobit model explained

In statistics, a tobit model is any of a class of regression models in which the observed range of the dependent variable is censored in some way.[1] The term was coined by Arthur Goldberger in reference to James Tobin,[2] who developed the model in 1958 to mitigate the problem of zero-inflated data for observations of household expenditure on durable goods.[3] Because Tobin's method can be easily extended to handle truncated and other non-randomly selected samples, some authors adopt a broader definition of the tobit model that includes these cases.[4]

Tobin's idea was to modify the likelihood function so that it reflects the unequal sampling probability for each observation depending on whether the latent dependent variable fell above or below the determined threshold.[5] For a sample that, as in Tobin's original case, was censored from below at zero, the sampling probability for each non-limit observation is simply the height of the appropriate density function. For any limit observation, it is the cumulative distribution, i.e. the integral below zero of the appropriate density function. The tobit likelihood function is thus a mixture of densities and cumulative distribution functions.[6]

The likelihood function

Below are the likelihood and log likelihood functions for a type I tobit. This is a tobit that is censored from below at

yL

when the latent variable
*
y
j

\leqyL

. In writing out the likelihood function, we first define an indicator function

I

:

I(y)=\begin{cases} 0&ify\leqyL,\\ 1&ify>yL. \end{cases}

Next, let

\Phi

be the standard normal cumulative distribution function and

\varphi

to be the standard normal probability density function. For a data set with N observations the likelihood function for a type I tobit is

l{L}(\beta,\sigma)=\prod

N
\left(
j=1
1
\sigma

\varphi\left(

yj-Xj\beta
\sigma
I(yj)
\right)\right)

\left(1-\Phi\left(

Xj\beta-yL
\sigma
1-I(yj)
\right)\right)

and the log likelihood is given by

\begin{align} logl{L}(\beta,\sigma)&=

n
\sum
j=1

I(yj)log\left(

1
\sigma

\varphi\left(

yj-Xj\beta
\sigma

\right)\right)+(1-I(yj))log\left(1-\Phi\left(

Xj\beta-yL
\sigma

\right)\right)\\ &=

\sum
yj>yL

log\left(

1
\sigma

\varphi\left(

yj-Xj\beta
\sigma

\right)\right)+

\sum
yj=yL

log\left(\Phi\left(

yL-Xj\beta
\sigma

\right)\right) \end{align}

Reparametrization

The log-likelihood as stated above is not globally concave, which complicates the maximum likelihood estimation. Olsen suggested the simple reparametrization

\beta=\delta/\gamma

and

\sigma2=\gamma-2

, resulting in a transformed log-likelihood,

logl{L}(\delta,\gamma)=

\sum
yj>yL

\left\{log\gamma+log\left[\varphi\left(\gammayj-Xj\delta\right)\right]\right\}+

\sum
yj=yL

log\left[\Phi\left(\gammayL-Xj\delta\right)\right]

which is globally concave in terms of the transformed parameters.[7]

For the truncated (tobit II) model, Orme showed that while the log-likelihood is not globally concave, it is concave at any stationary point under the above transformation.[8] [9]

Consistency

If the relationship parameter

\beta

is estimated by regressing the observed

yi

on

xi

, the resulting ordinary least squares regression estimator is inconsistent. It will yield a downwards-biased estimate of the slope coefficient and an upward-biased estimate of the intercept. Takeshi Amemiya (1973) has proven that the maximum likelihood estimator suggested by Tobin for this model is consistent.[10]

Interpretation

The

\beta

coefficient should not be interpreted as the effect of

xi

on

yi

, as one would with a linear regression model; this is a common error. Instead, it should be interpreted as the combination of (1) the change in

yi

of those above the limit, weighted by the probability of being above the limit; and (2) the change in the probability of being above the limit, weighted by the expected value of

yi

if above.[11]

Variations of the tobit model

Variations of the tobit model can be produced by changing where and when censoring occurs. classifies these variations into five categories (tobit type I – tobit type V), where tobit type I stands for the first model described above. Schnedler (2005) provides a general formula to obtain consistent likelihood estimators for these and other variations of the tobit model.[12]

Type I

The tobit model is a special case of a censored regression model, because the latent variable

*
y
i
cannot always be observed while the independent variable

xi

is observable. A common variation of the tobit model is censoring at a value

yL

different from zero:

yi=\begin{cases}

*
y
i

&if

*
y
i

>yL,\\ yL&if

*
y
i

\leqyL. \end{cases}

Another example is censoring of values above

yU

.

yi=\begin{cases}

*
y
i

&if

*
y
i

<yU,\\ yU&if

*
y
i

\geqyU. \end{cases}

Yet another model results when

yi

is censored from above and below at the same time.

yi=\begin{cases}

*
y
i

&ifyL<y

*
i

<yU,\\ yL&if

*
y
i

\leqyL,\\ yU&if

*
y
i

\geqyU. \end{cases}

The rest of the models will be presented as being bounded from below at 0, though this can be generalized as done for Type I.

Type II

Type II tobit models introduce a second latent variable.[13]

y2i=\begin{cases}

*
y
2i

&if

*
y
1i

>0,\\ 0&if

*
y
1i

\leq0. \end{cases}

In Type I tobit, the latent variable absorbs both the process of participation and the outcome of interest. Type II tobit allows the process of participation (selection) and the outcome of interest to be independent, conditional on observable data.

The Heckman selection model falls into the Type II tobit,[14] which is sometimes called Heckit after James Heckman.[15]

Type III

Type III introduces a second observed dependent variable.

y1i=\begin{cases}

*
y
1i

&if

*
y
1i

>0,\\ 0&if

*
y
1i

\leq0. \end{cases}

y2i=\begin{cases}

*
y
2i

&if

*
y
1i

>0,\\ 0&if

*
y
1i

\leq0. \end{cases}

The Heckman model falls into this type.

Type IV

Type IV introduces a third observed dependent variable and a third latent variable.

y1i=\begin{cases}

*
y
1i

&if

*
y
1i

>0,\\ 0&if

*
y
1i

\leq0. \end{cases}

y2i=\begin{cases}

*
y
2i

&if

*
y
1i

>0,\\ 0&if

*
y
1i

\leq0. \end{cases}

y3i=\begin{cases}

*
y
3i

&if

*
y
1i

\leq0,\\ 0&if

*
y
1i

<0. \end{cases}

Type V

Similar to Type II, in Type V only the sign of

*
y
1i
is observed.

y2i=\begin{cases}

*
y
2i

&if

*
y
1i

>0,\\ 0&if

*
y
1i

\leq0. \end{cases}

y3i=\begin{cases}

*
y
3i

&if

*
y
1i

\leq0,\\ 0&if

*
y
1i

>0. \end{cases}

Non-parametric version

If the underlying latent variable

*
y
i
is not normally distributed, one must use quantiles instead of moments to analyze the observable variable

yi

. Powell's CLAD estimator offers a possible way to achieve this.[16]

Applications

Tobit models have, for example, been applied to estimate factors that impact grant receipt, including financial transfers distributed to sub-national governments who may apply for these grants. In these cases, grant recipients cannot receive negative amounts, and the data is thus left-censored. For instance, Dahlberg and Johansson (2002) analyse a sample of 115 municipalities (42 of which received a grant).[17] Dubois and Fattore (2011) use a tobit model to investigate the role of various factors in European Union fund receipt by applying Polish sub-national governments.[18] The data may however be left-censored at a point higher than zero, with the risk of mis-specification. Both studies apply Probit and other models to check for robustness. Tobit models have also been applied in demand analysis to accommodate observations with zero expenditures on some goods. In a related application of tobit models, a system of nonlinear tobit regressions models has been used to jointly estimate a brand demand system with homoscedastic, heteroscedastic and generalized heteroscedastic variants.[19]

See also

Further reading

Notes and References

  1. Book: Hayashi, Fumio . Fumio Hayashi . Econometrics . limited . Princeton . Princeton University Press . 2000 . 0-691-01018-8 . 518–521 .
  2. Book: Goldberger, Arthur S. . Econometric Theory . registration . New York . J. Wiley . 1964 . 253–55 . 9780471311010 .
  3. Tobin . James . 1958 . Estimation of Relationships for Limited Dependent Variables . Econometrica . 26 . 1 . 24–36 . 1907382 . 10.2307/1907382 .
  4. Amemiya . Takeshi . Takeshi Amemiya . 1984 . Tobit Models: A Survey . . 24 . 1–2 . 3–61 . 10.1016/0304-4076(84)90074-5 .
  5. Book: Kennedy, Peter . Peter Kennedy (economist) . A Guide to Econometrics . Cambridge . MIT Press . Fifth . 2003 . 0-262-61183-X . 283–284 .
  6. Book: Bierens, Herman J. . Introduction to the Mathematical and Statistical Foundations of Econometrics . limited . Cambridge University Press . 2004 . 207 .
  7. Randall J. . Olsen . Note on the Uniqueness of the Maximum Likelihood Estimator for the Tobit Model . . 46 . 5 . 1978 . 1211–1215 . 10.2307/1911445 . 1911445 .
  8. Chris . Orme . On the Uniqueness of the Maximum Likelihood Estimator in Truncated Regression Models . Econometric Reviews . 8 . 1989 . 2 . 217–222 . 10.1080/07474938908800171 .
  9. Shigeru . Iwata . A Note on Multiple Roots of the Tobit Log Likelihood . . 56 . 3 . 1993 . 441–445 . 10.1016/0304-4076(93)90129-S .
  10. Amemiya . Takeshi . 1973 . Regression analysis when the dependent variable is truncated normal . . 41 . 6 . 997–1016 . 1914031 . 10.2307/1914031 .
  11. McDonald . John F. . Moffit . Robert A. . 1980 . The Uses of Tobit Analysis . . 62 . 2 . 318–321 . 1924766 . 10.2307/1924766 .
  12. Schnedler . Wendelin . 2005 . Likelihood estimation for censored random vectors . Econometric Reviews . 24 . 2 . 195–217 . 10.1081/ETC-200067925 . 10419/127228 . 55747319 .
  13. Book: Amemiya, Takeshi . Advanced econometrics . Harvard University Press . Cambridge, Mass . 1985 . 0-674-00560-0 . 11728277 . 384 . registration . Tobit Models .
  14. Heckman. James J.. Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error. Econometrica. 47. 1. 1979. 153–161. 0012-9682. 10.2307/1912352. 1912352.
  15. Sigelman. Lee. Zeng. Langche. Analyzing Censored and Sample-Selected Data with Tobit and Heckit Models. Political Analysis. 8. 2. 1999. 167–182. 1047-1987. 10.1093/oxfordjournals.pan.a029811. 25791605.
  16. Powell. James L. Least absolute deviations estimation for the censored regression model. Journal of Econometrics. 1 July 1984. 25. 3. 303–325. 10.1016/0304-4076(84)90004-6 . 10.1.1.461.4302.
  17. Dahlberg. Matz. Johansson. Eva. 2002-03-01. On the Vote-Purchasing Behavior of Incumbent Governments. American Political Science Review. 96. 1. 27–40. 10.1017/S0003055402004215. 1537-5943. 10.1.1.198.4112. 12718473.
  18. Dubois. Hans F. W.. Fattore. Giovanni. 2011-07-01. Public Fund Assignment through Project Evaluation. Regional & Federal Studies. 21. 3. 355–374. 10.1080/13597566.2011.578827. 154659642. 1359-7566.
  19. Baltas. George. 2001. Utility-consistent Brand Demand Systems with Endogenous Category Consumption: Principles and Marketing Applications. Decision Sciences. en. 32. 3. 399–422. 10.1111/j.1540-5915.2001.tb00965.x. 0011-7315.