Social heuristics explained

Social heuristics are simple decision making strategies that guide people's behavior and decisions in the social environment when time, information, or cognitive resources are scarce.[1] Social environments tend to be characterised by complexity and uncertainty, and in order to simplify the decision-making process, people may use heuristics, which are decision making strategies that involve ignoring some information or relying on simple rules of thumb.

The class of phenomena described by social heuristics overlap with those typically investigated by social psychology and game theory. At the intersection of these fields, social heuristics have been applied to explain cooperation in economic games used in experimental research. In the view of the field's academics, cooperation is typically advantageous in daily life, and therefore people develop a cooperation heuristic that gets applied even to one-shot anonymous interactions (the "social heuristics hypothesis" of human cooperation).[2]

Overview

Bounded rationality

See also: Bounded rationality. In the decision-making process, optimisation is almost always intractable in any implementation, whether machine or neural.[3] Because of this, defined parameters or boundaries must be implemented in the process in order to achieve an acceptable outcome. This method is known as applying bounded rationality, where an individual makes a collective and rational choice that considers “the limits of human capability to calculate, the severe deficiencies of human knowledge about the consequences of choice, and the limits of human ability to adjudicate among multiple goals”.[4] They are essentially incorporating a series of criteria, referred to as alternatives for choice. These alternatives are often not initially given to the decision maker, so a theory of search is also incorporated.[4]

Heuristics

See also: Heuristics in judgment and decision-making and Heuristic. Heuristics are a common alternative, which can be defined as simple strategies for decision making where the actor only pays attention to key pieces of information, allowing the decision to be made quickly and with less cognitive effort.[5]

Daniel Kahneman and Shane Frederick have advanced the view that heuristics are decision-making processes that employ attribute substitution, where the decision maker substitutes the "target attribute" of the thing he is trying to judge with a "heuristic attribute" that more easily comes to mind. Shah and Daniel M. Oppenheimer have framed heuristics in terms of effort reduction, where the decision maker makes use of techniques that make decisions less effortful, such as only paying attention to some cues or only considering a subset of the available alternatives.[6] Another view of heuristics comes from Gerd Gigerenzer and colleagues, who conceptualize heuristics as "fast and frugal" techniques for decision making that simplify complex calculations and make up part of the "adaptive toolbox" of human capacities for reasoning and inference.[7] Under this framework, heuristics are ecologically rational, meaning a heuristic may be successful if the way it works matches the demands of the environment it is being used in. Researchers in this vein also argue that heuristics may be just as or even more accurate when compared to more complex strategies, such as multiple regression.[8]

Social heuristics

Social heuristics can include heuristics that use social information, operate in social contexts, or both.[9] Examples of social information include information about the behavior of a social entity or the properties of a social system, while nonsocial information is information about something physical. Contexts in which an organism may use social heuristics can include "games against nature" and "social games". In games against nature, the organism strives to predict natural occurrences (such as the weather) or competes against other natural forces to accomplish something. In social games, the organism is making decisions in a situation that involves other social beings. Importantly, in social games, the most adaptive course of action also depends on the decisions and behavior of the other actors. For instance, the follow-the-majority heuristic uses social information as inputs but is not necessarily applied in a social context, while the equity-heuristic uses non-social information but can be applied in a social context such as the allocation of parental resources amongst offspring.

Within social psychology, some researchers have viewed heuristics as closely linked to cognitive biases.[10] Others have argued that these biases result from the application of social heuristics depending on the structure of the environment that they operate in.[11] Researchers in the latter approach treat the study of social heuristics as closely linked to social rationality, a field of research that applies the ideas of bounded rationality and heuristics to the realm of social environments. Under this view, social heuristics are seen as ecologically rational. In the context of evolution, research utilizing evolutionary simulation models has found support for the evolution of social heuristics and cooperation when the outcomes of social interactions are uncertain.[12]

Examples

Examples of social heuristics include:

Relation to other concepts

Dual-process approach

A dual-process approach to human cognition specifies two types of thought processes: one that is fast and happens unconsciously or automatically, and another that is slower and involves more conscious deliberation.[26] In the dominant dual-systems approach in social psychology, heuristics are believed to be automatically and unconsciously applied.[27] The study of social heuristics as a tool of bounded rationality asserts that heuristics may be used consciously or unconsciously.[28]

Social heuristics hypothesis

The social heuristics hypothesis is a theory put forth by Rand and colleagues that explains the link between intuition and cooperation. Under this theory, cooperating in everyday social situations tends to be successful, and as a result, cooperation is an internalized heuristic that is applied in unfamiliar social contexts, even those in which such behavior may not lead to the most personally advantageous result for the actor (such as a lab experiment).

Methods used by researchers to study cooperative behavior in the laboratory include economic games such as:[29]

These economic games all share the condition that, when played in a single round, an individual's payout is maximized if he acts selfishly and chooses not to cooperate. However, over the course of repeated rounds, cooperation can be payout maximizing and thus be a self-interested strategy.

Following a dual-process framework, the social heuristics hypothesis contends that cooperation, which is automatic and intuitive, may be overridden by reflection. The theory is supported by evidence from laboratory and online experiments suggesting that time pressure increases cooperation,[30] though some evidence suggests this may be only among individuals who are not as familiar with the types of economic games typically used in this field of research.

Meta-analytic evidence based on 67 studies that looked at cooperation in the types of economic games described above suggests that cognitive-processing manipulations that encourage intuitive decision-making (such as time pressure or increased cognitive load) increase pure cooperation, where a one-shot action has no future consequences for the actor to consider and not cooperating is the most advantageous option. However, such manipulations do not have an effect on strategic cooperation in situations in which cooperation may be the pay-off maximizing option because of a possibility of future interactions where the actor may be rewarded for cooperation.

Importantly, research suggests that this intuitive cooperation may vary by culture and/or social roles. For instance, one study comparing participants from the US to participants from India found some differences in the patterns and speed of cooperation in online tasks across these groups, suggesting that cultural background may play a role in cooperative behavior.[31] Another study comparing men to women found that promoting intuitive decision making increased cooperative behavior among women but not among men, and the authors link this result to social roles and norms that stereotype women as altruistic.[32]

See also

Notes and References

  1. Hertwig. Ralph. Herzog. Stefan M.. 2009-10-01. Fast and Frugal Heuristics: Tools of Social Rationality. Social Cognition. 27. 5. 661–698. 10.1521/soco.2009.27.5.661. 11858/00-001M-0000-002E-576B-B. 0278-016X. free. 2021-05-01. 2020-06-15. https://web.archive.org/web/20200615103401/https://guilfordjournals.com/doi/10.1521/soco.2009.27.5.661. live.
  2. 10.1038/ncomms4677. Social heuristics shape intuitive cooperation. Nature Communications. 5. 2014. Rand . D. G. . Peysakhovich . A. . Kraft-Todd . G. T. . Newman . G. E. . Wurzbacher . O. . Nowak . M. A. . Greene . J. D. . 24751464 . 3677. 2014NatCo...5.3677R. free .
  3. Gigerenzer. Gerd. 2004. Striking a blow for sanity in theories of rationality. Models of a Man: Essays in Memory of Herbert A. Simon. 1. 389–409. MIT Press. 2021-05-01. 2021-04-28. https://web.archive.org/web/20210428035637/https://yalebooks.yale.edu/book/9780300024326/models-thought. live.
  4. Simon. Herbert. 1979. Rational Decision Making in Business Organizations . The American Economic Review. 69. 4. 493–513. 1808698.
  5. Gigerenzer. Gerd. Gaissmaier. Wolfgang. 2010-12-02. Heuristic Decision Making. Annual Review of Psychology. 62. 1. 451–482. 10.1146/annurev-psych-120709-145346. 21126183. 11858/00-001M-0000-0024-F16D-5. 0066-4308. free. 2021-05-01. 2021-02-20. https://web.archive.org/web/20210220172052/https://www.annualreviews.org/doi/10.1146/annurev-psych-120709-145346. live.
  6. Shah. Anuj K.. Oppenheimer. Daniel M.. 2008. Heuristics made easy: An effort-reduction framework.. Psychological Bulletin. 134. 2. 207–222. 10.1037/0033-2909.134.2.207. 18298269. 1939-1455. 2021-05-01. 2021-05-01. https://web.archive.org/web/20210501184338/https://doi.apa.org/doiLanding?doi=10.1037%2F0033-2909.134.2.207. live.
  7. Book: Gigerenzer. Gerd. Simple heuristics that make us smart. Todd. Peter M. ABC Research Group. 1999. Oxford University Press. 0-585-35863-X. New York. 47009468. 2021-05-01. 2021-05-01. https://web.archive.org/web/20210501184320/https://www.worldcat.org/title/simple-heuristics-that-make-us-smart/oclc/47009468. live.
  8. Book: Czerlinkski. Jean. Simple Heuristics That Make Us Smart. Gigerenzer. Gerd. Goldstein. Daniel G.. Oxford University Press. 1999. 0195143817. How Good Are Simple Heuristics?.
  9. Book: Hertwig. R.. Simple Heuristics in a Social World. Hoffrage. U.. 2012. 9780195388435. Simple Heuristics: The Foundations of Adaptive Social Behavior. 10.1093/acprof:oso/9780195388435.003.0001. 11858/00-001M-0000-0024-EBE7-B.
  10. Krueger. J. I.. Funder. D. C.. 2004. Towards a balanced social psychology: Causes, consequences, and cures for the problem-seeking approach to social behavior and cognition. Behavioral and Brain Sciences. 27. 3. 313–27. 10.1017/S0140525X04000081. 15736870. 6260477. https://web.archive.org/web/20200227032232/https://pdfs.semanticscholar.org/a228/997ffba89231d4425cbbc234e60f8f19ad5e.pdf. dead. 2020-02-27.
  11. Pachur. T.. Hertwig. R.. Rieskamp. J. R.. 2013. Intuitive judgments of social statistics: How exhaustive does sampling need to be?. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology. 49. 6. 1059–1077. 10.1016/j.jesp.2013.07.004. free. 11858/00-001M-0000-0024-EBFB-0.
  12. van den Berg. Pieter. Wenseleers. Tom. 2018-05-31. Uncertainty about social interactions leads to the evolution of social heuristics. Nature Communications. en. 9. 1. 2151. 10.1038/s41467-018-04493-1. 2041-1723. 5981325. 29855472. 2018NatCo...9.2151V.
  13. Book: Boyd. Robert. The origin and evolution of cultures. Richerson. Peter J.. 2005. Oxford University Press. 1-4237-5685-1. Oxford. 64590314.
  14. Raz, O., & Ert, E. (2008). ""Size Counts": the Effect of Queue Length on Choice Between Similar Restaurants." NA - Advances in Consumer Research Volume 35 MN : Association for Consumer Research
  15. DeMiguel . Victor . Garlappi . Lorenzo . Uppal . Raman . 1/N . EFA 2006 Zurich Meetings . 2006 . 10.2139/ssrn.911512. 1–51. Zurich.
  16. Hertwig . R. . Davis . J. N. . Sulloway . F. J. . 10.1037/0033-2909.128.5.728 . Parental investment: How an equity motive can produce inequality . Psychological Bulletin . 128 . 5 . 728–745 . 2002 . 12206192. 10.1.1.459.2817 .
  17. Book: 978-0465021222 . The Evolution of Cooperation . registration . Robert Axelrod (political scientist) . 1984 . Axelrod . Robert M. . Basic Books .
  18. 10.1016/j.tics.2013.06.003. 23856025. Human cooperation. Trends in Cognitive Sciences. 17. 8. 413–25. 2013. Rand . D. G. . Nowak . M. A. . 1694051.
  19. Hart. Sergiu. 2005. Adaptive Heuristics. Econometrica. en. 73. 5. 1401–1430. 10.1111/j.1468-0262.2005.00625.x. 1468-0262. 2021-05-01. 2020-12-06. https://web.archive.org/web/20201206230059/https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/abs/10.1111/j.1468-0262.2005.00625.x. live.
  20. Goldstein. Daniel G.. Gigerenzer. Gerd. 2002. Models of ecological rationality: The recognition heuristic.. Psychological Review. en. 109. 1. 75–90. 10.1037/0033-295X.109.1.75. 11863042. 11858/00-001M-0000-0025-9128-B. 1939-1471. free. 2021-05-01. 2021-05-01. https://web.archive.org/web/20210501184338/https://doi.apa.org/doiLanding?doi=10.1037%2F0033-295X.109.1.75. live.
  21. Reimer. Torsten. Katsikopoulos. Konstantinos V.. 2004. The use of recognition in group decision-making. Cognitive Science. en. 28. 6. 1009–1029. 10.1207/s15516709cog2806_6. free.
  22. Hastie. Reid. Kameda. Tatsuya. 2005. The Robust Beauty of Majority Rules in Group Decisions.. Psychological Review. en. 112. 2. 494–508. 10.1037/0033-295X.112.2.494. 15783295. 1939-1471. 2021-05-01. 2021-05-01. https://web.archive.org/web/20210501184400/https://doi.apa.org/doiLanding?doi=10.1037%2F0033-295X.112.2.494. live.
  23. Book: Gilovich. Torsten. Griffin. D. Kahneman. D. 2002. Heuristics and Biases: The Psychology of Intuitive Judgment. 0-521-79260-6. Cambridge University Press. en. 2021-05-01. 2021-04-28. https://web.archive.org/web/20210428035625/https://assets.cambridge.org/97805217/92608/sample/9780521792608ws.pdf. live.
  24. Cervone. D. Peake. P. 2002. Anchoring, efficacy, and action: The influence of judgmental heuristics on self-efficacy judgments and behaviour. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology. 50. 3. 492–501. 10.1037/0022-3514.50.3.492. en. 2021-05-01. 2021-05-01. https://web.archive.org/web/20210501184401/https://doi.apa.org/doiLanding?doi=10.1037%2F0022-3514.50.3.492. live.
  25. Wright . William F . Anderson . Urton . Effects of situation familiarity and financial incentives on use of the anchoring and adjustment heuristic for probability assessment . Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes . August 1989 . 44 . 1 . 68–82 . 10.1016/0749-5978(89)90035-6.
  26. Evans. Jonathan St. B. T.. 2007-12-21. Dual-Processing Accounts of Reasoning, Judgment, and Social Cognition. Annual Review of Psychology. 59. 1. 255–278. 10.1146/annurev.psych.59.103006.093629. 18154502. 12246493 . 0066-4308. 2021-05-01. 2021-03-01. https://web.archive.org/web/20210301071842/https://www.annualreviews.org/doi/10.1146/annurev.psych.59.103006.093629. live.
  27. Book: Chaiken. Y.. Trope. Y.. 1999. Dual-process Theories in Social Psychology. Guilford Press. 9781572304215.
  28. Book: Gigerenzer. G. . 2004. Fast and frugal heuristics: The tools of bounded rationality. Blackwell handbook of judgment and decision making. 10.1002/9780470752937.ch4. Malden. Blackwell. 62–88. 11858/00-001M-0000-0025-872D-3 . D. J.. Koehler . N.. Harvey. 9780470752937.
  29. Rand. David G.. 2016-07-15. Cooperation, Fast and Slow: Meta-Analytic Evidence for a Theory of Social Heuristics and Self-Interested Deliberation. Psychological Science. en. 27. 9. 1192–1206. 10.1177/0956797616654455. 27422875. 5522004. 2021-05-01. 2020-11-12. https://web.archive.org/web/20201112192154/https://journals.sagepub.com/doi/10.1177/0956797616654455. live.
  30. Rand. David G.. Greene. Joshua D.. Nowak. Martin A.. 2012-09-20. Spontaneous giving and calculated greed. Nature. en. 489. 7416. 427–430. 10.1038/nature11467. 22996558. 2012Natur.489..427R. 4326080. 0028-0836. 2021-05-01. 2021-04-07. https://web.archive.org/web/20210407005235/https://www.nature.com/articles/nature11467. live.
  31. Nishi. Akihiro. Christakis. Nicholas A.. Rand. David G.. 2017-02-23. Cooperation, decision time, and culture: Online experiments with American and Indian participants. PLOS ONE. en. 12. 2. e0171252. 10.1371/journal.pone.0171252. 1932-6203. 5322955. 28231296. 2017PLoSO..1271252N. free.
  32. Rand. David G.. Brescoll. Victoria L.. Everett. Jim A. C.. Capraro. Valerio. Barcelo. Hélène. 2016. Social heuristics and social roles: Intuition favors altruism for women but not for men.. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General. en. 145. 4. 389–396. 10.1037/xge0000154. 26913619. 1939-2222. free.