In financial mathematics, a self-financing portfolio is a portfolio having the feature that, if there is no exogenous infusion or withdrawal of money, the purchase of a new asset must be financed by the sale of an old one. This concept is used to define for example admissible strategies and replicating portfolios, the latter being fundamental for arbitrage-free derivative pricing.
(\Omega,l{F},\{l{F}t\}
T,P) | |
t=0 |
Kt
p(K | |
L | |
t) |
=\{X\in
p(l{F} | |
L | |
T): |
X\inKt P-a.s.\}
(Ht)
T | |
t=0 |
for all
t\in\{0,1,...,T\}
Ht-Ht-1\in-Kt P-a.s.
H-1=0
If we are only concerned with the set that the portfolio can be at some future time then we can say that
H\tau\in-K0-
\tau | |
\sum | |
k=1 |
p(K | |
L | |
k) |
If there are transaction costs then only discrete trading should be considered, and in continuous time then the above calculations should be taken to the limit such that
\Deltat\to0
Let
S=(St)t\geq
h=(ht)t\geq
hi ⋅ Si
\foralli=1,...,d
i | |
h | |
t |
i
t
i | |
S | |
t |
i
h
Vt=
n | |
\sum | |
i=1 |
i | |
h | |
t |
i. | |
S | |
t |
Then the portfolio/the trading strategy
h=\left(
1, | |
(h | |
t |
...,
d)\right) | |
h | |
t |
Vt=
n | |
\sum | |
i=1 |
i | |
\left\{h | |
0 |
i | |
S | |
0 |
+
t | |
\int | |
0 |
i | |
h | |
u |
i | |
dS | |
u |
\right\}=h0 ⋅ S0+
t | |
\int | |
0 |
hu ⋅ dSu
h0 ⋅ S0
t | |
\int | |
0 |
hu ⋅ dSu
t