Integrability of demand explained
In microeconomic theory, the problem of the integrability of demand functions deals with recovering a utility function (that is, consumer preferences) from a given walrasian demand function.[1] The "integrability" in the name comes from the fact that demand functions can be shown to satisfy a system of partial differential equations in prices, and solving (integrating) this system is a crucial step in recovering the underlying utility function generating demand.
The problem was considered by Paul Samuelson in his book Foundations of Economic Analysis, and conditions for its solution were given by him in a 1950 article.[2] More general conditions for a solution were later given by Leonid Hurwicz and Hirofumi Uzawa.[3]
Mathematical formulation
Given consumption space
and a known
walrasian demand function
, solving the problem of integrability of demand consists in finding a utility function
such that
x(p,w)=\operatorname{argmax}x\{u(x):p ⋅ x\leqw\}
That is, it is essentially "reversing" the consumer's utility maximization problem.
Sufficient conditions for solution
for the consumer. Then, with the properties of expenditure functions, one can construct an at-least-as-good set
which is equivalent to finding a utility function
.
If the demand function
is
homogenous of degree zero, satisfies
Walras' Law, and has a negative semi-definte substitution matrix
, then it is possible to follow those steps to find a utility function
that generates demand
.
[4] Proof: if the first two conditions (homogeneity of degree zero and Walras' Law) are met, then duality between the expenditure minimization problem and the utility maximization problem tells us that
where
is the consumers'
indirect utility function and
is the consumers'
hicksian demand function. Fix a utility level
. From
Shephard's lemma, and with the identity above we have
where we omit the fixed utility level
for conciseness. is a system of
PDEs in the prices vector
, and
Frobenius' theorem can be used to show that if the matrix
is symmetric, then it has a solution. Notice that the matrix above is simply the substitution matrix
, which we assumed to be symmetric firsthand. So has a solution, and it is (at least theoretically) possible to find an expenditure function
such that
.
For the second step, by definition,
e(p)=e(p,u0)=min\{p ⋅ x:x\in
\}
where
. By the properties of
, it is not too hard to show
[4] that
=\{x\in
p ⋅ x\geqe(p,u0)\}
. Doing some algebraic manipulation with the inequality
, one can reconstruct
in its original form with
. If that is done, one has found a utility function
that generates consumer demand
.
Notes and References
- https://core.ac.uk/download/pdf/14705907.pdf
- Samuelson . Paul . Paul Samuelson . The Problem of Integrability in Utility Theory . Economia . 1950 . 17 . 68 . 355-385 . 10.2307/2549499 .
- Book: Hurwicz . Leonid . Uzawa . Hirofumi . Chipman . John S. . Richter . Marcel K. . Sonnenschein . Hugo F. . Hugo F. Sonnenschein . Preferences, utility, and demand: A Minnesota symposium. . 1971 . Harcourt, Brace, Jovanovich . New York . 114–148 . Chapter 6: On the integrability of demand functions.
- Book: Mas-Colell . Michael Whinston . Jerry Green (economist) . Mas-Colell. Andreu . Whinston . Micheal D. . Green . Jerry R.. 1995 . Microeconomic Theory . Oxford University Press . 75–80 . 978-0195073409.