Hattendorff's Theorem, attributed to K. Hattendorff (1868), is a theorem in actuarial science that describes the allocation of the variance or risk of the loss random variable over the lifetime of an actuarial reserve. In other words, Hattendorff's theorem demonstrates that the variation in the present value of the loss of an issued insurance policy can be allocated to the future years during which the insured is still alive. This, in turn, facilitates the management of risk prevalent in such insurance contracts over short periods of time.[1]
The main result of the theorem has three equivalent formulations:
where:
Variable | Explanation | |
---|---|---|
K(x) | The number of whole years that a life status x survives. If Tx K(x)=\lfloorTx\rfloor | |
kpj | Actuarial notation for Pr(j\leqTx<j+k) | |
\pij | The premium received by the insured in year j. | |
bj | The benefit paid to the insured in year j. | |
Lh | The actuarial present value of the total loss over the remaining life of the policy at time h. | |
Ch | The present value of the net cash loss from the policy in the year (h, h+1). | |
v | The discount factor for one year. | |
Λh | The present value of the net cash loss from the policy plus the change in total liabilities in the year (h, h+1). | |
Vh | The benefit reserve at time h, equal to E[Lh|K(x)\geqh] |
In its above formulation, and in particular the first result, Hattendorff's theorem states that the variance of
Lh
Λk
Source:[2]
In the most general stochastic setting in which the analysis of reserves is carried out, consider an insurance policy written at time zero, over which the insured pays yearly premiums
\pi0,\pi1...\piK(x)
K(x)+1
bK(x)+1
Suppose an insurance company is interested to know the cash loss from this policy over the year (h, h+1). Of course, if the death of the insured happens prior to time h, or when
K(x)<h
Ch=0
K(x)=h
vbh+1
Ch=vbh-\pih.
K(x)>h
Ch= \begin{cases} 0&ifK(x)=0,1...h-1\ vbh-\pih&ifK(x)=h\ -\pih&ifK(x)=h+1,h+2...\ \end{cases}
Furthermore, the actuarial present value of the future cash losses in each year has the explicit formula
Lh= \begin{cases} 0&ifK(x)=0,1...h-1\\ vbK(x)-\piK(x)&ifK(x)=h\\ vK(x)bK(x)-
K(x) | |
\sum | |
k=h |
vk-h\pik&ifK(x)=h+1,h+2... \end{cases}
In the analysis of reserves, a central quantity of interest is the benefit reserve
Vh
Vh=E[Lh|K(x)\geqh]
which admits to the closed form expression
Vh=
infty | |
\sum | |
k=0 |
\left(vkbk-
k | |
\sum | |
j=0 |
vj\pij+h\right){kpx+h
Lastly, the present value of the net cash loss at time h over the year (h, h+1), denoted
Λh
Ch
PV(\DeltaVh)
Λh=Ch+v\DeltaLiabilities
K(x)>h
Λh=-\pih+(vVh+1-Vh)
K(x)=h
Λh=(vbh+1-\pih)-Vh
K(x)<h
Λh=0
Λh=\begin{cases} 0&ifK(x)=0,1...h-1\\ (vbh+1-\pih)-Vh&ifK(x)=h\\ (vVh+1-Vh)-\pih&ifK(x)=h+1,h+2... \end{cases}.
The proof of the first equality is written as follows. First, by writing the present value of future net losses at time h,
infty | |
\begin{align} \sum | |
k=h |
vkΛk&=
infty | |
\sum | |
k=h |
vk[Ck+v\DeltaLiabilitiesinyear(k,k+1)]\\ &=
infty | |
\sum | |
k=h |
vkCk+
infty | |
\sum | |
k=h |
vk\DeltaLiabilitiesinyear(k,k+1)\\ &=Lh+
infty | |
\sum | |
k=h |
vk(vVk+1-Vk)\\ &=Lh+
infty | |
\sum | |
k=h |
v(kVk+1-
infty | |
\sum | |
k=h |
vkVk\\ \end{align}
from which it is easy to see that
Lh=
infty | |
\sum | |
k=h |
vkΛk+Vh.
It is known that the individual net cash flows in different years are uncorrelated, or
Cov(ΛhΛj|K(x)\geqk)=0
k\leqh<j
Var[Lh|K(x)\geqh]=
infty | |
Var\left[\sum | |
k=h |
vkΛk+Vh|K(x)\geqh\right]=
infty | |
\sum | |
k=h |
v2(kVar[Λk|K(x)\geqh]
which proves the first part of the theorem. The reader is referred to (Bowers et al., pg 241) for the proof of the other equalities.