Expenditure function explained

In microeconomics, the expenditure function gives the minimum amount of money an individual needs to spend to achieve some level of utility, given a utility function and the prices of the available goods.

Formally, if there is a utility function

u

that describes preferences over n commodities, the expenditure function

e(p,u*):

n
bfR
+

x bfR bfR

says what amount of money is needed to achieve a utility

u*

if the n prices are given by the price vector

p

.This function is defined by

e(p,u*)=

min
x\in\geq(u*)

px

where

\geq(u*)=\{x\in

n
bfR
+

:u(x)\gequ*\}

is the set of all bundles that give utility at least as good as

u*

.

Expressed equivalently, the individual minimizes expenditure

x1p1+...+xnpn

subject to the minimal utility constraint that

u(x1,...,xn)\geu*,

giving optimal quantities to consume of the various goods as
*,
x
1

...

*
x
n
as function of

u*

and the prices; then the expenditure function is

e(p1,...,pn;

*)=p
u
1
*+...
x
1

+pn

*.
x
n

Features of Expenditure Functions

(Properties of the Expenditure Function) Suppose u is a continuous utility function representing a locally non-satiated preference relation º on Rn +. Then e(p, u) is

1.   Homogeneous of degree one in p: for all and

λ>0

,

e(λp,u)e(p,u);

2.   Continuous in

p

and

u;

3.   Nondecreasing in

p

and strictly increasing in

u

provided

p\gg0;

4.   Concave in

p

5. If the utility function is strictly quasi-concave, there is the Shephard's lemmaProof

(1) As in the above proposition, note that

e(λ

p,u)=min
n
x\inR:u(x)\gequ
+

λpx

min
n
x\inR:u(x)\gequ
+

pxe(p,u)

(2) Continue on the domain

e

:
N*bfR
bfR
++

bfR

(3) Let

p\prime>p

and suppose

x\inh(p\prime,u)

. Then

u(h)\gequ

, and

e(p\prime,u)=p\primex\geqpx

. It follows immediately that

e(p,u)\leqe(p\prime,u)

.

For the second statement, suppose to the contrary that for some

u\prime>u

,

e(p,u\prime)\leqe(p,u)

Than, for some

x\inh(p,u)

,

u(x)=u\prime>u

, which contradicts the "no excess utility" conclusion of the previous proposition

(4)Let

t\in(0,1)

and suppose

x\inh(tp+(1-t)p\prime)

. Then,

px\geqe(p,u)

and

p\primex\geqe(p\prime,u)

, so

e(tp+(1-t)p\prime,u)=(tp+(1-t)p\prime)x\geq

te(p,u)+(1-t)e(p\prime,u)

.

(5)

\delta(p0,u0)
\deltapi
0,u
=x
i(p

0)

Expenditure and indirect utility

The expenditure function is the inverse of the indirect utility function when the prices are kept constant. I.e, for every price vector

p

and income level

I

:

e(p,v(p,I))\equivI

There is a duality relationship between expenditure function and utility function. If given a specific regular quasi-concave utility function, the corresponding price is homogeneous, and the utility is monotonically increasing expenditure function, conversely, the given price is homogeneous, and the utility is monotonically increasing expenditure function will generate the regular quasi-concave utility function. In addition to the property that prices are once homogeneous and utility is monotonically increasing, the expenditure function usually assumes

(1) is a non-negative function, i.e.,

E(Pu)>O;

(2) For P, it is non-decreasing, i.e.,

E(p1u)>E(p2u),u>Opl>p2>ON

;

(3)E(Pu) is a concave function. That is,

e(npl+(1-n)p2)u)>λE(p1u)(1-n)E(p2u)y>0

O<λ<1pl\geq

2
O
Np

\geqON

Expenditure function is an important theoretical method to study consumer behavior. Expenditure function is very similar to cost function in production theory. Dual to the utility maximization problem is the cost minimization problem [1] [2]

Example

u(x1,x2)=

.6
x
1
.4
x
2

,

which generates the demand functions[3]

x1(p1,p2,I)=

.6I
p1

    {\rmand}   x2(p1,p2,I)=

.4I
p2

,

where

I

is the consumer's income. One way to find the expenditure function is to first find the indirect utility function and then invert it. The indirect utility function

v(p1,p2,I)

is found by replacing the quantities in the utility function with the demand functions thus:

v(p1,p2,I)=

*,
u(x
1
*)
x
2

=

*)
(x
1

.6

*)
(x
2

.4=\left(

.6I
p1

\right).6\left(

.4I
p2

\right).4=(.6.6 x .4.4)I.6+.4

-.6
p
1
-.4
p
2

=K

-.6
p
1
-.4
p
2

I,

where

K=(.6.6 x .4.4).

Then since

e(p1,p2,u)=e(p1,p2,v(p1,p2,I))=I

when the consumer optimizes, we can invert the indirect utility function to find the expenditure function:

e(p1,p2,u)=(1/K)

.6
p
1
.4
p
2

u,

Alternatively, the expenditure function can be found by solving the problem of minimizing

(p1x1+p2x2)

subject to the constraint

u(x1,x2)\gequ*.

This yields conditional demand functions
*(p
x
1,

p2,u*)

and
*(p
x
1,

p2,u*)

and the expenditure function is then

e(p1,p2,u*)=p1x

*+
1

p2x

*
2

See also

Further reading

Notes and References

  1. Book: Jing ji xue da ci dian. 1994. Tuan jie chu ban she. Xiaomin Liang, 梁小民.. 7-80061-954-0. Di 1 ban. Beijing Shi. 34287945.
  2. Web site: CONSUMER CHOICE AND DUALITY.
  3. Book: Varian, H. . 1992 . Microeconomic Analysis . registration . 3rd . New York . W. W. Norton ., pp. 111, has the general formula.