The Diamond coconut model is an economic model constructed by the American economist and 2010 Nobel laureate Peter Diamond which analyzes how a search economy in which traders cannot find partners instantaneously operates. The model was first presented in a 1982 paper published in the Journal of Political Economy. The main implication of the model is that people's expectations as to the level of aggregate activity play a crucial role in actually determining this level of aggregate economic activity. A frequent interpretation of its conclusion, as applied to the labor market, is that the so-called natural rate of unemployment may not be unique (in fact there may exist a continuum of "natural rates") and even if it is unique, it may not be efficient. Diamond's model was of interest to New Keynesian economists who saw it as potential source of coordination failure, which could cause markets to fail to clear.[1]
The model takes its name from the abstract set up imagined by Diamond. He envisioned an island (a closed economy) populated by individuals who only consume coconuts. Coconuts are obtained by being picked (they are "produced") from palm trees at a cost. Because of a particular taboo existing on this island a person who has picked a coconut cannot consume it themselves but must find another person with a coconut. At that point the two individuals can trade their respective coconuts and eat them. The key point is that when an individual finds a palm tree, because climbing the tree is costly, they will only be willing to climb it to get a coconut if there are a sufficiently high number of other individuals who are willing to do likewise. If nobody else is obtaining coconuts then there won't be any potential trading partners and obtaining coconuts is not worth climbing the tree. Hence, what individuals believe others will do plays a crucial role in determining the overall outcome. As a result, people's (fully rational) expectations become a self-fulfilling prophecy and the economy can wind up with multiple equilibria, most if not all of them characterized by inefficiency.
The agents in the model are always in one of two "states"; they are either currently carrying a coconut and looking for someone to trade it with, or they are searching for a palm tree in order to possibly pick a coconut. The number of agents who are carrying a coconut at time t is denoted by
e(t)
b(e(t))
y
The fact that the probability of finding a trading partner is increasing in the number of people who already have coconuts - mathematically
b'(e)>0
People who are currently looking for coconut palm trees find these at a random rate
f
f
e(t)
1-e(t)
The figure above illustrates the population flows in this economy.
Each state can be thought of as a form of an asset, for example, the asset "having a coconut". The present discounted value of this asset depends on the benefit or cost incurred when a person finds a trading partner or a palm tree (this is like a one time dividend payment), and the capital gain (or loss) involved in switching states when a trade or coconut-picking occurs. Additionally, out of steady state, the value of the asset may fluctuate over time.
Mathematically, the present discounted value of having a coconut is given by
rVe=b(e)(y+Vu-V
|
where
Ve
Vu
y
r
rVu=f(-E(c)+Ve-V
|
where
f
E(c)
In the general version of the model, the cost of climbing a palm tree is a random draw from some (publicly known) probability distribution with non-negative support, for example the uniform distribution on
(clow,chi)
In the most simple version of Diamond's model, the probability of finding a trading partner—another person who's carrying a coconut—is exactly equal to the share of the population that is currently in possession of a coconut,
b(e)=e
c
The evolution of the proportion of people who are currently carrying coconuts and looking for trading partners is given by:
de | |
dt |
=f(1-e)-b(e)e=f(1-e)-e2
de | |
dt |
=-e2
In the first equation
f(1-e)
t
e2
In the steady state of this economy, the number of searchers and the number of coconut carriers has to be constant,
de | |
dt |
=0
e*=0
e*=(1/2)(-f+\sqrt{f2+4f})
Whether or not the good outcome is possible depends on parameter values, and as these determine the value of each asset in steady state. In this case the value of the assets will be constant so that
dVe | = | |
dt |
dVu | |
dt |
=0
Ve
Vu
Ve-V
|
For it to be worth it to climb a palm tree this difference has to be greater than the cost of climbing a tree. If
e*=0
fc/(r+f)>c
e=0
e> | rc |
y-c |
e
f
e*
f
e
r
e=0
c
r