DeGroot learning explained
DeGroot learning refers to a rule-of-thumb type of social learning process. The idea was stated in its general form by the American statistician Morris H. DeGroot; antecedents were articulated by John R. P. French and Frank Harary. The model has been used in physics, computer science and most widely in the theory of social networks.[1]
Setup and the learning process
Take a society of
agents where everybody has an opinion on a subject, represented by a vector of probabilities
. Agents obtain no new information based on which they can update their opinions but they communicate with other agents. Links between agents (who knows whom) and the weight they put on each other's opinions is represented by a trust matrix
where
is the weight that agent
puts on agent
's opinion. The trust matrix is thus in a one-to-one relationship with a weighted,
directed graph where there is an edge between
and
if and only if
. The trust matrix is
stochastic, its rows consists of nonnegative real numbers, with each row summing to 1.
Formally, the beliefs are updated in each period as
so the
th period opinions are related to the initial opinions by
Convergence of beliefs and consensus
An important question is whether beliefs converge to a limit and to each other in the long run. As the trust matrix is stochastic, standard results in Markov chain theory can be used to state conditions under which the limit
p(infty)=\limtp(t)=\limtTtp(0)
exists for any initial beliefs
. The following cases are treated in Golub and Jackson (2010).
Strongly connected case
If the social network graph (represented by the trust matrix) is strongly connected, convergence of beliefs is equivalent to each of the following properties:
is
aperiodic
of
corresponding to
eigenvalue 1 whose entries sum to 1 such that, for every
,
\left(\limtTtp\right)i=s ⋅ p
for every
where
denotes the
dot product.The equivalence between the last two is a direct consequence from
Perron–Frobenius theorem.
General case
It is not necessary to have a strongly connected social network to have convergent beliefs, however,the equality of limiting beliefs does not hold in general.
We say that a group of agents
is
closed if for any
,
only if
. Beliefs are convergent if and only if every set of nodes (representing individuals) that is strongly connected and closed is also
aperiodic.
Consensus
A group
of individuals is said to reach a
consensus if
for any
. This means that, as a result of the learning process, in the limit they have the same belief on the subject.
With a strongly connected and aperiodic network the whole group reaches a consensus.In general, any strongly connected and closed group
of individuals reaches a consensus for every initial vector of beliefs if and only if it is aperiodic. If, for example, there are two groups satisfying these assumptions, they reach a consensus inside the groups but there is not necessarily a consensus at the society level.
Social influence
Take a strongly connected and aperiodic social network. In this case, the common limiting belief is determined by the initial beliefs through
where
is the unique unit length
left eigenvector of
corresponding to the
eigenvalue 1. The vector
shows the weights that agents put on each other's initial beliefs in the consensus limit. Thus, the higher is
, the more
influence individual
has on the consensus belief.
The eigenvector property
implies that
This means that the influence of
is a weighted average of those agents' influence
who pay attention to
, with weights of their level of trust. Hence influential agents are characterized by being trusted by other individuals with high influence.
Examples
These examples appear in Jackson (2008).
Convergence of beliefs
Consider a three-individual society with the following trust matrix:
T=\begin{pmatrix}
0&1/2&1/2\\
1&0&0\\
0&1&0\\
\end{pmatrix}
Hence the first person weights the beliefs of the other two with equally, while the second listens only to the first, the third only to the second individual.For this social trust structure, the limit exists and equals
\limtTtp(0)=\left(\limtTt\right)p(0)=\begin{pmatrix}
2/5&2/5&1/5\\
2/5&2/5&1/5\\
2/5&2/5&1/5\\
\end{pmatrix}p(0)
so the influence vector is
s=\left(2/5,2/5,1/5\right)
and the consensus belief is
2/5p1(0)+2/5p2(0)+1/5p3(0)
. In words, independently of the initial beliefs, individuals reach a consensus where the initial belief of the first and the second person has twice ashigh influence than the third one's.
Non-convergent beliefs
If we change the previous example such that the third person also listens exclusively to the firstone, we have the following trust matrix:
T=\begin{pmatrix}
0&1/2&1/2\\
1&0&0\\
1&0&0\\
\end{pmatrix}
In this case for any
we have
T2k=\begin{pmatrix}
0&1/2&1/2\\
1&0&0\\
1&0&0\\
\end{pmatrix}
and
T2k=\begin{pmatrix}
1&0&0\\
0&1/2&1/2\\
0&1/2&1/2\\
\end{pmatrix}
so
does not exist and beliefs do not converge in the limit. Intuitively, 1 is updating based on 2 and 3's beliefs while2 and 3 update solely based on 1's belief so they interchange their beliefs in each period.
Asymptotic properties in large societies: wisdom
It is possible to examine the outcome of the DeGroot learning process in large societies,that is, in the
limit.
Let the subject on which people have opinions be a "true state"
. Assume that individualshave
independent noisy signals
of
(now superscript refers to time, the argument to the size of the society).Assume that for all
the trust matrix
is such that the limiting beliefs
exists independently from the initial beliefs. Then the sequence of societies
is called
wise if
maxi|
-\mu|\xrightarrow{ p }0
where
denotes
convergence in probability.This means that if the society grows without bound, over time they will have a common and accurate belief on the uncertain subject.
A necessary and sufficient condition for wisdom can be given with the help of influence vectors. A sequence of societies is wise if and onlyif
that is, the society is wise precisely when even the most influential individual's influence vanishes in the large society limit. For further characterization and examples see Golub and Jackson (2010).
References
- Book: Koley . Gaurav . Deshmukh . Jayati . Srinivasa . Srinath . Social Informatics . Social Capital as Engagement and Belief Revision . 2020 . Aref . Samin . Bontcheva . Kalina . Braghieri . Marco . Dignum . Frank . Giannotti . Fosca . Grisolia . Francesco . Pedreschi . Dino . https://link.springer.com/chapter/10.1007/978-3-030-60975-7_11 . Lecture Notes in Computer Science . 12467 . en . Cham . Springer International Publishing . 137–151 . 10.1007/978-3-030-60975-7_11 . 978-3-030-60975-7. 222233101 .