Charles F. Manski Explained

Charles F. Manski
Birth Date:27 November 1948
Birth Place:Boston, Massachusetts, U.S.
Institution:Northwestern University
University of Wisconsin-Madison
Hebrew University of Jerusalem
Carnegie-Mellon University
Field:Econometrics
Alma Mater:Massachusetts Institute of Technology
Boston Latin School
Doctoral Advisor:Franklin M. Fisher
Doctoral Students:Francesca Molinari
Spouses:-->
Repec Prefix:e
Repec Id:pma111

Charles Frederick Manski (born November 27, 1948) is an American economist and university professor at the Northwestern University. Manski is a noted econometrician, known for his work in rational choice theory and an innovator in the area of parameter identification.[1] His research spans econometrics, judgment and decision, and the analysis of social policy (such as work on school choice). A specialist in prediction and decision, he is known within the economics field for landmark work on partial identification, identification of discrete choice models, and identification of social interactions. He has also performed substantial empirical research on measurement of expectations in surveys.

Manski was predicted to win the Nobel Prize in 2015 by Reuters along with two other economists. Chicago economist John A. List for his work on field experiments and English economist Richard Blundell for his work on labor markets were also listed as favorites to win a future Nobel Prize.

Early life

He is the son of Holocaust survivor and Sugihara visa recipient Samuil Manski[2] and Estelle Zonn Manski. He grew up in Dorchester and West Roxbury, both in Massachusetts, attended Boston Latin School, and spent many afternoons in the family diner.[3] One day, while leading a Torah reading, he had an epiphany that led him away from religious studies and towards scientific skepticism:

"[I] learned something about why dogmas can be tenacious and irreconcilable. Many doctrines pose nonrefutable hypotheses. That is, they make statements about the world that are impossible to disprove. For example, it is impossible to disprove the hypothesis that the god of the Torah created the universe in six days and then rested on the seventh day. It is similarly impossible to disprove the hypothesis that the universe was created by the Flying Spaghetti Monster."[4]

Personal life

Manski is married to Catherine Manski, a lecturer in the Department of Education at the University of Illinois at Chicago.[5] He has two children, educator Rebecca Manski and sociologist Ben Manski, and three grandchildren.[6]

Academic career

He received his B.S. and Ph.D. in economics from MIT in 1970 and 1973. He first taught at Carnegie Mellon University (1973–1980), moving on to the Hebrew University of Jerusalem (1978–1983), and joining the faculty of the University of Wisconsin–Madison (U.W., 1983–1998). While at the U.W., Manski served as Director of the Institute for Research on Poverty (1988–1991) and as Chair of the Board of Overseers of the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (1994–1998). Since 1997 Manski has been Board of Trustees Professor in Economics at Northwestern University.[7]

Manski has served as a member of the National Research Council's (NRC) Committee on National Statistics (1996–2000), and the Commission on Behavioral and Social Sciences and Education (1992–1998). At the NRC, he has been Chair of the Committee on Data and Research for Policy on Illegal Drugs (1998–2001) and a member of the Board on Mathematical Sciences and their Applications (2004–2007) and the Committee on Law and Justice (2009–). Manski is an elected fellow of the Econometric Society, The American Academy of Arts and Sciences, and the American Association for the Advancement of Science.[7] In 2009, Manski was elected to the National Academy of Sciences; he is one of 2 economists elected to the body in 2009 and one of about 60 economists elected up to that point.[8] In 2014 he was elected a Corresponding Fellow of the British Academy.[9]

War on Drugs

Manski served on the NRC's Committee on Data and Research for Policy on Illegal Drugs, which studied the war on drugs. The committee report found that existing studies on efforts to address drug usage and smuggling, from US military operations to eradicate coca fields in Colombia, to domestic drug treatment centers, have all been inconclusive, if the programs have been evaluated at all: "The existing drug-use monitoring systems are strikingly inadequate to support the full range of policy decisions that the nation must make.... It is unconscionable for this country to continue to carry out a public policy of this magnitude and cost without any way of knowing whether and to what extent it is having the desired effect."[10] The study was mentioned by the press but was initially ignored by policymakers, leading Manski to conclude, as one observer noted, that "the drug war has no interest in its own results."[11]

Research

Manski's work in econometrics includes the development of tools for partial identification, the maximum score estimator for discrete choice models, and work on the "reflection problem" in models of peer effects.

As of 2007, Manski's research interests focus primarily on the field of formation of social policy with partial knowledge of treatment response. Economists and doctors alike share a common interest in gauging the effect of various "treatments" delivered to "patients."[12] Since research on treatment response rarely provides sufficient information to determine effectiveness, how should the available evidence be employed in choosing future treatments?[13]

Election predictions

In 2004, Manski challenged the theoretical basis for statements in the popular media "that markets can predict an election better than polls and experts can."[14]

Selected publications

Partial identification
Identification of discrete choice models
Identification of social interactions
Measurement of expectations in surveys
Other

Further reading

External links

Notes and References

  1. Charles Manski, Partial Identification of Probability Distributions, New York: Springer-Verlag, 2003.
  2. Book: Manski, Samuil . With God's Help . 1990 . 2019-06-16.
  3. Web site: CharlesManski.com. October 9, 2015.
  4. Unlearning and Discovery. Manski. Charles. Spring 2010. The American Economist. 55. 9–18. 10.1177/056943451005500102. 33759962. October 9, 2015.
  5. Web site: UIC English Department. https://web.archive.org/web/20090202082059/http://tigger.uic.edu/depts/engl/index.html. 2009-02-02. dead.
  6. Web site: Charles F. Manski: About Charles Manski. www.charlesmanski.com. 2015-10-10.
  7. Web site: Charles Manski biography at Northwestern . 2019-06-16.
  8. http://www.northwestern.edu/newscenter/stories/2009/05/manskihonor.html "Charles Manski Elected to National Academy of Sciences"
  9. Web site: British Academy announces 42 new fellows . Times Higher Education . 18 July 2014 . 18 July 2014.
  10. Web site: No Data on Effectiveness . September 27, 2013 . https://web.archive.org/web/20081205024427/http://www.dpeg.org/dpeg_2001_spg.pdf . December 5, 2008 . bot: unknown ., Drug Policy Education Group, Vol. 2 No.1, Spring/Summer 2001, p.5
  11. http://www.drugsense.org/dsw/2001/ds01.n215.html "Weekly News in Review"
  12. Web site: Charles Manski biography at Institute for Policy Research . 2008-05-10 . 2011-11-08 . https://web.archive.org/web/20111108152538/http://www.northwestern.edu/ipr/people/manski.html . dead .
  13. C. Manski, Social Choice with Partial Knowledge of Treatment Response, Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2005.C. Manski, "Diversified Treatment under Ambiguity," International Economic Review, 2009, forthcoming.
  14. Stix, Gary. "Super Tuesday: Markets Predict Outcome Better Than Polls"; Scientific American, February 2008