Brownian model of financial markets explained

The Brownian motion models for financial markets are based on the work of Robert C. Merton and Paul A. Samuelson, as extensions to the one-period market models of Harold Markowitz and William F. Sharpe, and are concerned with defining the concepts of financial assets and markets, portfolios, gains and wealth in terms of continuous-time stochastic processes.

Under this model, these assets have continuous prices evolving continuously in time and are driven by Brownian motion processes.[1] This model requires an assumption of perfectly divisible assets and a frictionless market (i.e. that no transaction costs occur either for buying or selling). Another assumption is that asset prices have no jumps, that is there are no surprises in the market. This last assumption is removed in jump diffusion models.

Financial market processes

Consider a financial market consisting of

N+1

financial assets, where one of these assets, called a bond or money market, is risk free while the remaining

N

assets, called stocks, are risky.

Definition

A financial market is defined as

l{M}=(r,b,\delta,\sigma,A,S(0))

that satisfies the following:
  1. A probability space

(\Omega,l{F},P)

.
  1. A time interval

[0,T]

.
  1. A

D

-dimensional Brownian process

W(t)=(W1(t)\ldotsWD(t))',

where

0\leqt\leqT

adapted to the augmented filtration

\{l{F}(t);0\leqt\leqT\}

.
  1. A measurable risk-free money market rate process

r(t)\inL1[0,T]

.
  1. A measurable mean rate of return process

b:[0,T] x RNR\inL2[0,T]

.
  1. A measurable dividend rate of return process

\delta:[0,T] x RNR\inL2[0,T]

.
  1. A measurable volatility process

\sigma:[0,T] x RNR

, such that
N
\sum
n=1
D
\sum
d=1
T
\int
0
2(s)ds
\sigma
n,d

<infty

.
  1. A measurable, finite variation, singularly continuous stochastic

A(t)

.
  1. The initial conditions given by

S(0)=(S0(0),\ldotsSN(0))'

.

The augmented filtration

Let

(\Omega,l{F},p)

be a probability space, and a

W(t)=(W1(t)\ldotsWD(t))',0\leqt\leqT

beD-dimensional Brownian motion stochastic process, with the natural filtration:

l{F}W(t)\triangleq\sigma\left(\{W(s);0\leqs\leqt \}\right),\forallt\in[0,T].

If

l{N}

are the measure 0 (i.e. null undermeasure

P

) subsets of

l{F}W(t)

, then definethe augmented filtration:

l{F}(t)\triangleq\sigma\left(l{F}W(t)\cup l{N}\right),\forallt\in[0,T]

The difference between

\{l{F}W(t);0\leqt\leqT\}

and

\{l{F}(t);0\leqt\leqT\}

is that thelatter is both left-continuous, in the sense that:

l{F}(t)=\sigma\left(cup0\leql{F}(s) \right),

and right-continuous, such that:

l{F}(t)=captl{F}(s),

while the former is only left-continuous.[2]

Bond

A share of a bond (money market) has price

S0(t)>0

at time

t

with

S0(0)=1

, is continuous,

\{l{F}(t);0\leqt\leqT\}

adapted, and has finite variation. Because it has finite variation, it can be decomposed into an absolutely continuous part
a
S
0(t)
and a singularly continuous part
s
S
0(t)
, by Lebesgue's decomposition theorem. Define:

r(t)\triangleq

1
S0(t)
d
dt
a
S
0(t),

and

A(t)\triangleq

t
\int
0
1
S0(s)
s
dS
0(s),

resulting in the SDE:

dS0(t)=S0(t)[r(t)dt+dA(t)],\forall0\leqt\leqT,

which gives:

S0(t)=

t
\exp\left(\int
0

r(s)ds+A(t)\right),\forall0\leqt\leqT.

Thus, it can be easily seen that if

S0(t)

is absolutely continuous (i.e.

A()=0

), then the price of the bond evolves like the value of a risk-free savings account with instantaneous interest rate

r(t)

, which is random, time-dependent and

l{F}(t)

measurable.

Stocks

Stock prices are modeled as being similar to that of bonds, except with a randomly fluctuating component (called its volatility). As a premium for the risk originating from these random fluctuations, the mean rate of return of a stock is higher than that of a bond.

Let

S1(t)\ldotsSN(t)

be the strictly positive prices per share of the

N

stocks, which are continuous stochastic processes satisfying:

dSn(t)=Sn(t)\left[bn(t)dt+dA(t)+

D
\sum
d=1

\sigman,d(t)dWd(t)\right],\forall0\leqt\leqT,n=1\ldotsN.

Here,

\sigman,d(t),d=1\ldotsD

gives the volatility of the

n

-th stock, while

bn(t)

is its mean rate of return.

In order for an arbitrage-free pricing scenario,

A(t)

must be as defined above. The solution to this is:

Sn(t)=Sn(0)\exp\left(\int

t
0
D
\sum
d=1

\sigman,d(s)dWd(s)+

t
\int
0

\left[bn(s)-

1
2
D
\sum
d=1
2
\sigma
n,d

(s)\right]ds+A(t)\right),\forall0\leqt\leqT,n=1\ldotsN,

and the discounted stock prices are:

Sn(t)
S0(t)

=Sn(0)\exp\left(\int

t
0
D
\sum
d=1

\sigman,d(s)dWd(s)+

t
\int
0

\left[bn(s)-r(s)-

1
2
D
\sum
d=1
2
\sigma
n,d

(s)\right]ds\right),\forall0\leqt\leqT,n=1\ldotsN.

Note that the contribution due to the discontinuities in the bond price

A(t)

does not appear in this equation.

Dividend rate

Each stock may have an associated dividend rate process

\deltan(t)

giving the rate of dividend payment per unit price of the stock at time

t

. Accounting for this in the model, gives the yield process

Yn(t)

:

dYn(t)=Sn(t)\left[bn(t)dt+dA(t)+

D
\sum
d=1

\sigman,d(t)dWd(t)+\deltan(t)\right],\forall0\leqt\leqT,n=1\ldotsN.

Portfolio and gain processes

Definition

Consider a financial market

l{M}=(r,b,\delta,\sigma,A,S(0))

.

A portfolio process

(\pi0,\pi1,\ldots\piN)

for this market is an

l{F}(t)

measurable,

RN+1

valued process such that:
T
\int
0

|

N\pi
\sum
n(t)|

\left[|r(t)|dt+dA(t)\right]<infty

, almost surely,
T
\int
0
N\pi
|\sum
n(t)[b

n(t)+\deltan(t)-r(t)]|dt<infty

, almost surely, and
T
\int
0
N\sigma
\sum
n,d
2
(t)\pi
n(t)|

dt<infty

, almost surely.

The gains process for this portfolio is:

G(t)\triangleq

t
\int
0
N\pi
\left[\sum
n(t)\right]\left(r(s)ds

+dA(s)\right)+

t
\int
0
N\pi
\left[\sum
n(t)\left(b

n(t)+\deltan(t)-r(t)\right)\right]dt+

t
\int
0
N\sigma
\sum
n,d

(t)\pin(t)dWd(s)0\leqt\leqT

We say that the portfolio is self-financed if:

G(t)=

N
\sum
n=0

\pin(t)

.

It turns out that for a self-financed portfolio, the appropriate value of

\pi0

is determined from

\pi=(\pi1,\ldots\piN)

and therefore sometimes

\pi

is referred to as the portfolio process. Also,

\pi0<0

implies borrowing money from the money-market, while

\pin<0

implies taking a short position on the stock.

The term

bn(t)+\deltan(t)-r(t)

in the SDE of

G(t)

is the risk premium process, and it is the compensation received in return for investing in the

n

-th stock.

Motivation

Consider time intervals

0=t0<t1<\ldots<tM=T

, and let

\nun(tm)

be the number of shares of asset

n=0\ldotsN

, held in a portfolio during time interval at time

[tm,tm+1m=0\ldotsM-1

. To avoid the case of insider trading (i.e. foreknowledge of the future), it is required that

\nun(tm)

is

l{F}(tm)

measurable.

Therefore, the incremental gains at each trading interval from such a portfolio is:

G(0)=0,

G(tm+1)-G(tm)=

N
\sum
n=0

\nun(tm)[Yn(tm+1)-Yn(tm)],m=0\ldotsM-1,

and

G(tm)

is the total gain over time

[0,tm]

, while the total value of the portfolio is
N
\sum
n=0

\nun(tm)Sn(tm)

.

Define

\pin(t)\triangleq\nun(t)

, let the time partition go to zero, and substitute for

Y(t)

as defined earlier, to get the corresponding SDE for the gains process. Here

\pin(t)

denotes the dollar amount invested in asset

n

at time

t

, not the number of shares held.

Income and wealth processes

Definition

Given a financial market

l{M}

, then a cumulative income process

\Gamma(t)0\leqt\leqT

is a semimartingale and represents the income accumulated over time

[0,t]

, due to sources other than the investments in the

N+1

assets of the financial market.

A wealth process

X(t)

is then defined as:

X(t)\triangleqG(t)+\Gamma(t)

and represents the total wealth of an investor at time

0\leqt\leqT

. The portfolio is said to be

\Gamma(t)

-financed
if:

X(t)=

N
\sum
n=0

\pin(t).

The corresponding SDE for the wealth process, through appropriate substitutions, becomes:

dX(t)=d\Gamma(t)+X(t)\left[r(t)dt+dA(t)\right]+

N
\sum
n=1

\left[\pin(t)\left(bn(t)+\deltan(t)-r(t)\right)\right]+

D
\sum
d=1
N
\left[\sum
n=1

\pin(t)\sigman,d(t)\right]dWd(t)

.

Note, that again in this case, the value of

\pi0

can be determined from

\pin,n=1\ldotsN

.

Viable markets

The standard theory of mathematical finance is restricted to viable financial markets, i.e. those in which there are no opportunities for arbitrage. If such opportunities exists, it implies the possibility of making an arbitrarily large risk-free profit.

Definition

In a financial market

l{M}

, a self-financed portfolio process

\pi(t)

is considered to be an arbitrage opportunity if the associated gains process

G(T)\geq0

, almost surely and

P[G(T)>0]>0

strictly. A market

l{M}

in which no such portfolio exists is said to be viable.

Implications

In a viable market

l{M}

, there exists a

l{F}(t)

adapted process

\theta:[0,T] x RDR

such that for almost every

t\in[0,T]

:

bn(t)+\deltan(t)-r(t)=

D
\sum
d=1

\sigman,d(t)\thetad(t)

.

This

\theta

is called the market price of risk and relates the premium for the

n

-the stock with its volatility

\sigman,

.

Conversely, if there exists a D-dimensional process

\theta(t)

such that it satisfies the above requirement, and:
T
\int
0
D
\sum
d=1
2
|\theta
d(t)|

dt<infty

E\left[\exp\left\{

T
-\int
0
D
\sum
d=1

\thetad(t)dWd(t)-

1
2
T
\int
0
D
\sum
d=1
2
|\theta
d(t)|

dt\right\}\right]=1

,

then the market is viable.

Also, a viable market

l{M}

can have only one money-market (bond) and hence only one risk-free rate. Therefore, if the

n

-th stock entails no risk (i.e.

\sigman,d=0,d=1\ldotsD

) and pays no dividend (i.e.

\deltan(t)=0

), then its rate of return is equal to the money market rate (i.e.

bn(t)=r(t)

) and its price tracks that of the bond (i.e.

Sn(t)=Sn(0)S0(t)

).

Standard financial market

Definition

A financial market

l{M}

is said to be standard if:

(i) It is viable.

(ii) The number of stocks

N

is not greater than the dimension

D

of the underlying Brownian motion process

W(t)

.

(iii) The market price of risk process

\theta

satisfies:
T
\int
0
D
\sum
d=1
2
|\theta
d(t)|

dt<infty

, almost surely.

(iv) The positive process

Z0(t)=\exp\left\{

t
-\int
0
D
\sum
d=1

\thetad(t)dWd(t)-

1
2
t
\int
0
D
\sum
d=1
2
|\theta
d(t)|

dt\right\}

is a martingale.

Comments

In case the number of stocks

N

is greater than the dimension

D

, in violation of point (ii), from linear algebra, it can be seen that there are

N-D

stocks whose volatilities (given by the vector

(\sigman,1\ldots\sigman,D)

) are linear combination of the volatilities of

D

other stocks (because the rank of

\sigma

is

D

). Therefore, the

N

stocks can be replaced by

D

equivalent mutual funds.

The standard martingale measure

P0

on

l{F}(T)

for the standard market, is defined as:

P0(A)\triangleqE[Z0(T)1A],\forallA\inl{F}(T)

.

Note that

P

and

P0

are absolutely continuous with respect to each other, i.e. they are equivalent. Also, according to Girsanov's theorem,

W0(t)\triangleqW(t)+

t
\int
0

\theta(s)ds

,

is a

D

-dimensional Brownian motion process on the filtration

\{l{F}(t);0\leqt\leqT\}

with respect to

P0

.

Complete financial markets

A complete financial market is one that allows effective hedging of the risk inherent in any investment strategy.

Definition

Let

l{M}

be a standard financial market, and

B

be an

l{F}(T)

-measurable random variable, such that:
P
0\left[B
S0(T)

>-infty\right]=1

.

x\triangleq

E
0\left[B
S0(T)

\right]<infty

,

The market

l{M}

is said to be complete if every such

B

is financeable, i.e. if there is an

x

-financed portfolio process

(\pin(t);n=1\ldotsN)

, such that its associated wealth process

X(t)

satisfies

X(t)=B

, almost surely.

Motivation

If a particular investment strategy calls for a payment

B

at time

T

, the amount of which is unknown at time

t=0

, then a conservative strategy would be to set aside an amount

x=\sup\omegaB(\omega)

in order to cover the payment. However, in a complete market it is possible to set aside less capital (viz.

x

) and invest it so that at time

T

it has grown to match the size of

B

.

Corollary

A standard financial market

l{M}

is complete if and only if

N=D

, and the

N x D

volatility process

\sigma(t)

is non-singular for almost every

t\in[0,T]

, with respect to the Lebesgue measure.

See also

Notes

  1. Tsekov. Roumen. Brownian Markets. 2013. Chin. Phys. Lett.. 088901. 30. 8. 10.1088/0256-307X/30/8/088901. 1010.2061. 2013ChPhL..30h8901T. 18675919.
  2. Book: Karatzas, Ioannis . Shreve, Steven E. . Brownian motion and stochastic calculus . 1991 . Springer-Verlag . New York . 0-387-97655-8 .

References

Book: Karatzas, Ioannis . Shreve, Steven E. . Methods of mathematical finance . 1998 . Springer . New York . 0-387-94839-2 .

Book: Korn, Ralf . Korn, Elke . Option pricing and portfolio optimization: modern methods of financial mathematics . 2001 . American Mathematical Society . Providence, R.I. . 0-8218-2123-7 .

R. C. . Robert C. Merton. Lifetime Portfolio Selection under Uncertainty: the Continuous-Time Case . The Review of Economics and Statistics . 51. 3. Merton . 247–257. 1 August 1969 . 0034-6535 . 10.2307/1926560. 1926560 . 8863885. https://web.archive.org/web/20191112101300/https://pdfs.semanticscholar.org/d3a2/3083ab2ecdeb0c99cf8d3b7b7b9d954f6ab8.pdf . dead . 12 November 2019 .

Optimum consumption and portfolio rules in a continuous-time model . 1970 . Merton, R.C. . Journal of Economic Theory . 373–413 . 3 . 4 . 10.1016/0022-0531(71)90038-x . 1721.1/63980 . free .